Despite
the rapid expansion of services in the economies of
developed and developing countries, it still remains
true that a nation's economic strength is in the final
analysis based on the strength of its commodity producing
sectors. Also, given the more rapid pace of productivity
expansion in manufacturing, the creation of a substantial
and dynamic manufacturing sector has historically
been the centre-piece of development strategies.
Seen from that perspective, there is much that is
disconcerting about the development process resulting
from the adoption of a neo-liberal reform agenda in
the 1990s. To start with, despite claims to the contrary
by the government, manufacturing growth performance
during the 1990s and more recently has been worse
than in the 1980s. Not only has the trend rate of
growth tended to be at best similar to that observed
in the 1980s, but the pace of manufacturing growth
has tended to be extremely volatile with creditable
growth rates being concentrated in one or two year
periods separated by slow growth and recessionary
conditions. Second, there are some signs of the "hollowing
of the middle" in Indian industry, with growth
occurring in the very large scale sector, while the
medium and small scale industry has witnessed slow
growth and high rates of mortality because of competition
from imports or import intensive "domestic"
products, a recessionary environment, waning state
support and inadequate credit access at times of distress.
The small scale sector that tends to persist is that
which caters to the ancillarization needs of large
firms, to niche markets and to low margin markets
that persist because of low per capita income and
high poverty. Third, there are clear signs of consolidation
within the large industrial sector, in which foreign
firms encouraged by liberalization of rules governing
foreign direct investment, play a major part. Since
these firms invest and expand in India to cater to
domestic and not export markets and since they are
characterized by large outflows on account of intermediate
imports, royalty payments and profit repatriation,
their growing presence not only limits the maneuverability
of the government when it comes to industrial policy,
but also has adverse balance of payments implications
in the form of a rising trade deficit that encourages
dependence on purely financial flows to help finance
that deficit. Finally, the most disconcerting feature
of industrial development during the 1990s is the
lack of any contribution of output growth in the organized
sector to employment growth. In fact, there appears
to be a negative relation between output and employment
growth. While it is known that the manufacturing sector
tends to be far less labour-absorbing than agriculture
or services, this feature of growth in organized industry
is extremely disturbing and needs correction.
There is reason to believe that most of these features
of manufacturing growth during the neo-liberal era
were a direct result of policy, defined as consciously
designed acts of commission and omission. These have
had implications for both the pace of growth and its
volatility, as well as for the pattern of growth with
several attendant consequences as noted above. Consider,
for example, the fact that a feature of the 1990s
was the extreme volatility of growth rates in the
manufacturing sector, which in the past had been more
characteristic of areas like finance. This instability
also suggests that even the moderately positive performance
of the industrial sector may not be sustainable.
There are two factors that seem to explain instability.
On the one hand, the evidence indicates that public
expenditure has been far more unstable in the 1990s.
The latter has been partly because of variations in
the government's degree of adherence to its irrational
fiscal deficit targets initially imposed by the IMF,
partly because of a sudden burgeoning of public expenditure
towards the end of the 1990s because of the implementation
of the Fifth Pay Commission's recommendations, and
partly because of the influence of the political business
cycle that results in a ramping up of public expenditures
of certain kinds in the run up to an election. It
needs to be noted that it was not the agricultural
cycle that influenced the government's inter-temporal
expenditure patterns (as used to be the case when
the agrarian constraint was binding in the sixties
and seventies); not was it the threat of a balance
of payments crisis that constrained government expenditure
(despite the experience of 1990-91, India has recently
foreign capital flows in excess of that needed to
finance its current account deficit). But for the
moment what matters is that the instability in government
expenditure that contributed in part to the instability
in industrial growth has been the result of autonomous
actions of the government rather than the result of
externally imposed constraints.
The second factor explaining the instability in manufacturing
growth is the fact that in the initial post-liberalization
years, the sudden increase in access to domestically
assembled or produced import-intensive manufactured
goods resulted in the release of the pent-up demand
for such goods among sections who had had the ability
and the desire to consume such goods, but whose consumption
of such commodities was limited by import regulation
of both final products and intermediates and components.
Inasmuch as such pent-up demand is soon satiated,
the spur to growth provided by this specific factor
evaporated, resulting in a slowing of the growth rate
pending an expansion of the market for such manufactures
among a larger section of the population.
Finally, instability in the pace of manufacturing
growth has been the result of the specific way in
which that market for manufactures has been expanded,
especially in urban India, during the years of neo-liberal
reform: through a boom in housing and consumer credit.
One consequence of financial liberalization and the
excess liquidity in the system created by the inflow
of foreign capital, has been the growing importance
of credit provided to individuals for specific purposes
such as purchases of property, consumer durables and
automobiles of various kinds. This implies a degree
of dissaving on the part of individuals and households.
It also implies that financial institutions, which
are willing to provide such credit without any collateral,
are betting on the inter-temporal income profile of
these individuals, since they are seen as being in
a position to meet their interest payment and amortization
commitments based on speculative projections of their
earnings profile. These projections are speculative
because of the fact that with banks and other financial
institutions competing with each other in the housing
and consumer finance markets, individuals can easily
take on excess debt from multiple sources, without
revealing to any individual creditor their possible
over-exposure to debt.
There are two implications of the expansion of the
market for manufactures through these means. The occurrence
and the extent of such an expansion depend crucially
on the "confidence" of both lenders and
borrowers. Lenders need to be confident of the future
ability of their clients to meet interest and repayment
commitments. Borrowers (excluding those consciously
involved in fraud) need to be confident of their ability
to meet in the future the commitments that they are
taking on in the present. This crucial role of the
"state of confidence" in triggering this
form of demand is what is captured in the oft-used
phrase: "the feel good factor". Since there
is a strong speculative element involved in lenders
providing credit and borrowers increasing their indebtedness,
the state of confidence of both parties matters. When
such confidence is "good", we can experience
growth or even a mini-boom. When such confidence is
low in the case of either borrowers or lenders, we
can experience recessionary conditions. To the extent
that financial liberalization provides the basis for
an expansion of the world of debt - mediated either
through bank accounts or plastic cards - a degree
of volatility in manufactures demand is inevitable.
The second implication of debt-financed manufacturing
demand is that it is inevitably concentrated in the
first instance in a narrow range of commodities that
are the targets of personal finance. Commodities vary
from construction materials to automobiles and consumer
durables. To the extent that these commodities are
of a kind that are capital- and import-intensive in
nature, the domestic employment and linkage effects
of this expansion would be limited. Not only would
employment growth be limited, as has been the case,
but sustaining the growth process would require generating
more of the same kind of demand. Manufacturing growth
would become increasingly of a speculative character.
It hardly bears stating that a large share of the
commodities for which demand is triggered by credit
are both capital- and import-intensive in character.
There are a number of other reasons why manufacturing
outputs sucked out by a credit boom tend to have these
characteristics. First, the liberalization of policy
with regard to foreign direct investment has meant
that much of the credit-financed "new" market
for manufactures is catered to by these transnationals,
endowing these products with a greater degree of import-
and capital-intensity. This tendency has been helped
along by the fact that those favoured with credit
fall in the middle classes, which too is characterized
by a pent-up demand for "foreign" goods
that could not be satiated earlier, not just because
of protection but also because they lacked the means
(including credit) to acquire these commodities rapidly.
A second reason why domestic linkage and employment
effects would tend to be low is that a combination
of import competition, the induction of larger firms
into the small-scale sector through the redefinition
of "small" and "dereservation"
of areas of production has undermined the ability
of smaller firms to service certain markets. Finally,
with end of the era of development banking in general
and directed credit in particular, the possibility
of such firms obtaining the finance to emerge and
survive has declined.
The net effect of all these has been the set of disconcerting
trends we spoke of earlier. Identifying the proximate
causes for those trends also helps us specify certain
measures that must be part of any industrial policy
agenda. In the long run, a conducive industrial environment
requires significant structural change such as the
breakdown of land monopoly in rural India, in order
to expand the mass market for manufactures. While
the realization of that goal must wait, the decision
of the new government, as embodied in the CMP, to
launch on a pro-poor development path, provides the
basis for the correction of the errors in policy during
the 1990s that have generated the scenario that we
just described. That scenario was one characterized
by speculative debt-financed consumption and dissaving,
growing import intensity of domestic production and
a sharp rise in capital intensity that implied "job-displacing
growth".
There are four elements that in our view should enter
into any interim industrial policy. First, the role
of public expenditure, especially public investment
as an important stimulus to industrial expansion,
through direct demand expansion and income generation
and by relaxing infrastructural bottlenecks, needs
to be restored. This requires reversing the decline
in the tax-GDP ratio, increasing revenue collection
through more appropriate rates and a wider tax net
and focusing on generating additional non-tax revenues
by reorganizing the public sector rather than resorting
to quick privatization of profit-making public enterprises.
It also requires encouraging demand based on income
growth rather than debt expansion. Second, the role
of finance as a stimulus to manufacturing dominantly
through debt-financed consumption spending must be
replaced by one in which financial institutions dominantly
support investment through lending and investment.
This requires reversing the tendency to undermine
the development finance institutions by converting
them into universal banks. Further, the earlier tendency
of the financial institutions to lend to a few big
firms in a few areas, which led up to the UTI-debacle
for example, must be corrected. More widespread lending,
including to small and medium sized firms is crucial
if the phenomenon of job-displacing growth in manufacturing
is to be reversed.
There is one possibility that needs to be considered
seriously in this context. The commercialization of
development banking has seen the increasing presence
of the financial institutions as active traders in
domestic stock markets in search of high returns.
This speculative presence in the market, which increases
the ratio of their assets held for speculative as
opposed to productive purposes, needs to be curtailed.
However, over the years these institutions have not
merely accumulated non-performing assets in the form
of credit to some of the leading corporate groups
in India, but they have also acquired a large volume
of debt and equity in well-performing large firms.
Having supported the growth of these firms and business
houses, it is perhaps time for the financial institutions
to gradually withdraw from these locations by selling
out their assets and using the funds so acquired to
finance new ventures of a kind characteristic of a
dynamic economy.
This implies that new legislation that helps financial
institutions pursue firms in which they hold non-performing
assets should be implemented. Innovative practices
like securitization of debt to withdraw from debt
provided to more successful business groups should
be adopted. And financial institutions should resort
to a careful process of sell out of equity acquired
(either directly or through the exercise of the convertibility
option) in successful firms in the past. All this
would help release resources that could go into financing
new and needy projects. This would partially reduce
the pressure on the government to increase the investment
ratio in the economy by investing its own budgetary
resources.
The third area in which the government should make
changes is with regard to foreign direct investment.
Such investment is indeed required and can play an
important role if of an appropriate kind. But foreign
investment, which acquires large chunks of equity
in firms catering to the domestic market, uses these
firms to market import-intensive branded products
and then takes out large amounts of foreign exchange
in the form of technology payments and dividends,
needs to be regulated. The obvious adverse balance
of payments implications of the operations of these
firms, implies that to earn their profits they are
draining the national pool of foreign exchange resources
which is then refurbished with capital in the form
of hot money that not merely drains out further foreign
exchange but increases the vulnerability of the system
to financial crises. It is perfectly rational as well
as reasonable that foreign firms with equity holding
above a certain limit and extracting large technology
payments should at the minimum earn the foreign exchange
that they propose to take out. Further, in terms of
emphasis, the effort should be to encourage foreign
investment that uses India as the outsourcing base
for world market production, with positive net employment
and balance of payments effects. If outsourcing in
software and IT-enabled services is seen as such a
major source of strength for India, there is no reason
why outsourcing in manufacturing should not be seen
as positive, and provided more privileges than foreign
investment catering primarily to the domestic market
and regulated for balance of payments reasons.
Finally, industrial policy should encourage small
scale production with both employment and linkage
effects in mind. Protecting small scale production
with the employment objective in mind in a labour-surplus
economy is not a form of charitable intervention but
rational economic policy. This was recognized by Mahalanobis
in his four-sector model which explicitly provided
for small and cottage production as a means of neutralizing
the adverse employment implications of investment
in capital-intensive sectors. Such protection would
involve a rethink of excessive import liberalization
in sectors where small-scale production is viable,
a restitution of measures of protection like reservation
of production and differential tariffs, and a conscious
direction of credit from the appropriate financial
institutions to meet investment and working capital
needs.
These are some of the principal measures that the
government can adopt immediately to redress the distortions
which indiscriminate liberalization parading as "reform"
has resulted in.
July 5, 2004.
|