Despite the rapid expansion of services
in the economies of developed and developing countries, it still remains
true that a nation's economic strength is in the final analysis based
on the strength of its commodity producing sectors. Also, given the more
rapid pace of productivity expansion in manufacturing, the creation of
a substantial and dynamic manufacturing sector has historically been the
centre-piece of development strategies.
Seen from that perspective, there is much that is disconcerting about
the development process resulting from the adoption of a neo-liberal reform
agenda in the 1990s. To start with, despite claims to the contrary by
the government, manufacturing growth performance during the 1990s and
more recently has been worse than in the 1980s. Not only has the trend
rate of growth tended to be at best similar to that observed in the 1980s,
but the pace of manufacturing growth has tended to be extremely volatile
with creditable growth rates being concentrated in one or two year periods
separated by slow growth and recessionary conditions. Second, there are
some signs of the "hollowing of the middle" in Indian industry,
with growth occurring in the very large scale sector, while the medium
and small scale industry has witnessed slow growth and high rates of mortality
because of competition from imports or import intensive "domestic"
products, a recessionary environment, waning state support and inadequate
credit access at times of distress. The small scale sector that tends
to persist is that which caters to the ancillarization needs of large
firms, to niche markets and to low margin markets that persist because
of low per capita income and high poverty. Third, there are clear signs
of consolidation within the large industrial sector, in which foreign
firms encouraged by liberalization of rules governing foreign direct investment,
play a major part. Since these firms invest and expand in India to cater
to domestic and not export markets and since they are characterized by
large outflows on account of intermediate imports, royalty payments and
profit repatriation, their growing presence not only limits the maneuverability
of the government when it comes to industrial policy, but also has adverse
balance of payments implications in the form of a rising trade deficit
that encourages dependence on purely financial flows to help finance that
deficit. Finally, the most disconcerting feature of industrial development
during the 1990s is the lack of any contribution of output growth in the
organized sector to employment growth. In fact, there appears to be a
negative relation between output and employment growth. While it is known
that the manufacturing sector tends to be far less labour-absorbing than
agriculture or services, this feature of growth in organized industry
is extremely disturbing and needs correction.
There is reason to believe that most of these features of manufacturing
growth during the neo-liberal era were a direct result of policy, defined
as consciously designed acts of commission and omission. These have had
implications for both the pace of growth and its volatility, as well as
for the pattern of growth with several attendant consequences as noted
above. Consider, for example, the fact that a feature of the 1990s was
the extreme volatility of growth rates in the manufacturing sector, which
in the past had been more characteristic of areas like finance. This instability
also suggests that even the moderately positive performance of the industrial
sector may not be sustainable.
There are two factors that seem to explain instability. On the one hand,
the evidence indicates that public expenditure has been far more unstable
in the 1990s. The latter has been partly because of variations in the
government's degree of adherence to its irrational fiscal deficit targets
initially imposed by the IMF, partly because of a sudden burgeoning of
public expenditure towards the end of the 1990s because of the implementation
of the Fifth Pay Commission's recommendations, and partly because of the
influence of the political business cycle that results in a ramping up
of public expenditures of certain kinds in the run up to an election.
It needs to be noted that it was not the agricultural cycle that influenced
the government's inter-temporal expenditure patterns (as used to be the
case when the agrarian constraint was binding in the sixties and seventies);
not was it the threat of a balance of payments crisis that constrained
government expenditure (despite the experience of 1990-91, India has recently
foreign capital flows in excess of that needed to finance its current
account deficit). But for the moment what matters is that the instability
in government expenditure that contributed in part to the instability
in industrial growth has been the result of autonomous actions of the
government rather than the result of externally imposed constraints.
The second factor explaining the instability in manufacturing growth is
the fact that in the initial post-liberalization years, the sudden increase
in access to domestically assembled or produced import-intensive manufactured
goods resulted in the release of the pent-up demand for such goods among
sections who had had the ability and the desire to consume such goods,
but whose consumption of such commodities was limited by import regulation
of both final products and intermediates and components. Inasmuch as such
pent-up demand is soon satiated, the spur to growth provided by this specific
factor evaporated, resulting in a slowing of the growth rate pending an
expansion of the market for such manufactures among a larger section of
the population.
Finally, instability in the pace of manufacturing growth has been the
result of the specific way in which that market for manufactures has been
expanded, especially in urban India, during the years of neo-liberal reform:
through a boom in housing and consumer credit. One consequence of financial
liberalization and the excess liquidity in the system created by the inflow
of foreign capital, has been the growing importance of credit provided
to individuals for specific purposes such as purchases of property, consumer
durables and automobiles of various kinds. This implies a degree of dissaving
on the part of individuals and households. It also implies that financial
institutions, which are willing to provide such credit without any collateral,
are betting on the inter-temporal income profile of these individuals,
since they are seen as being in a position to meet their interest payment
and amortization commitments based on speculative projections of their
earnings profile. These projections are speculative because of the fact
that with banks and other financial institutions competing with each other
in the housing and consumer finance markets, individuals can easily take
on excess debt from multiple sources, without revealing to any individual
creditor their possible over-exposure to debt.
There are two implications of the expansion of the market for manufactures
through these means. The occurrence and the extent of such an expansion
depend crucially on the "confidence" of both lenders and borrowers.
Lenders need to be confident of the future ability of their clients to
meet interest and repayment commitments. Borrowers (excluding those consciously
involved in fraud) need to be confident of their ability to meet in the
future the commitments that they are taking on in the present. This crucial
role of the "state of confidence" in triggering this form of
demand is what is captured in the oft-used phrase: "the feel good
factor". Since there is a strong speculative element involved in
lenders providing credit and borrowers increasing their indebtedness,
the state of confidence of both parties matters. When such confidence
is "good", we can experience growth or even a mini-boom. When
such confidence is low in the case of either borrowers or lenders, we
can experience recessionary conditions. To the extent that financial liberalization
provides the basis for an expansion of the world of debt - mediated either
through bank accounts or plastic cards - a degree of volatility in manufactures
demand is inevitable.
The second implication of debt-financed manufacturing demand is that it
is inevitably concentrated in the first instance in a narrow range of
commodities that are the targets of personal finance. Commodities vary
from construction materials to automobiles and consumer durables. To the
extent that these commodities are of a kind that are capital- and import-intensive
in nature, the domestic employment and linkage effects of this expansion
would be limited. Not only would employment growth be limited, as has
been the case, but sustaining the growth process would require generating
more of the same kind of demand. Manufacturing growth would become increasingly
of a speculative character.
It hardly bears stating that a large share of the commodities for which
demand is triggered by credit are both capital- and import-intensive in
character. There are a number of other reasons why manufacturing outputs
sucked out by a credit boom tend to have these characteristics. First,
the liberalization of policy with regard to foreign direct investment
has meant that much of the credit-financed "new" market for
manufactures is catered to by these transnationals, endowing these products
with a greater degree of import- and capital-intensity. This tendency
has been helped along by the fact that those favoured with credit fall
in the middle classes, which too is characterized by a pent-up demand
for "foreign" goods that could not be satiated earlier, not
just because of protection but also because they lacked the means (including
credit) to acquire these commodities rapidly. A second reason why domestic
linkage and employment effects would tend to be low is that a combination
of import competition, the induction of larger firms into the small-scale
sector through the redefinition of "small" and "dereservation"
of areas of production has undermined the ability of smaller firms to
service certain markets. Finally, with end of the era of development banking
in general and directed credit in particular, the possibility of such
firms obtaining the finance to emerge and survive has declined.
The net effect of all these has been the set of disconcerting trends we
spoke of earlier. Identifying the proximate causes for those trends also
helps us specify certain measures that must be part of any industrial
policy agenda. In the long run, a conducive industrial environment requires
significant structural change such as the breakdown of land monopoly in
rural India, in order to expand the mass market for manufactures. While
the realization of that goal must wait, the decision of the new government,
as embodied in the CMP, to launch on a pro-poor development path, provides
the basis for the correction of the errors in policy during the 1990s
that have generated the scenario that we just described. That scenario
was one characterized by speculative debt-financed consumption and dissaving,
growing import intensity of domestic production and a sharp rise in capital
intensity that implied "job-displacing growth".
There are four elements that in our view should enter into any interim
industrial policy. First, the role of public expenditure, especially public
investment as an important stimulus to industrial expansion, through direct
demand expansion and income generation and by relaxing infrastructural
bottlenecks, needs to be restored. This requires reversing the decline
in the tax-GDP ratio, increasing revenue collection through more appropriate
rates and a wider tax net and focusing on generating additional non-tax
revenues by reorganizing the public sector rather than resorting to quick
privatization of profit-making public enterprises. It also requires encouraging
demand based on income growth rather than debt expansion. Second, the
role of finance as a stimulus to manufacturing dominantly through debt-financed
consumption spending must be replaced by one in which financial institutions
dominantly support investment through lending and investment. This requires
reversing the tendency to undermine the development finance institutions
by converting them into universal banks. Further, the earlier tendency
of the financial institutions to lend to a few big firms in a few areas,
which led up to the UTI-debacle for example, must be corrected. More widespread
lending, including to small and medium sized firms is crucial if the phenomenon
of job-displacing growth in manufacturing is to be reversed.
There is one possibility that needs to be considered seriously in this
context. The commercialization of development banking has seen the increasing
presence of the financial institutions as active traders in domestic stock
markets in search of high returns. This speculative presence in the market,
which increases the ratio of their assets held for speculative as opposed
to productive purposes, needs to be curtailed. However, over the years
these institutions have not merely accumulated non-performing assets in
the form of credit to some of the leading corporate groups in India, but
they have also acquired a large volume of debt and equity in well-performing
large firms. Having supported the growth of these firms and business houses,
it is perhaps time for the financial institutions to gradually withdraw
from these locations by selling out their assets and using the funds so
acquired to finance new ventures of a kind characteristic of a dynamic
economy.
This implies that new legislation that helps financial institutions pursue
firms in which they hold non-performing assets should be implemented.
Innovative practices like securitization of debt to withdraw from debt
provided to more successful business groups should be adopted. And financial
institutions should resort to a careful process of sell out of equity
acquired (either directly or through the exercise of the convertibility
option) in successful firms in the past. All this would help release resources
that could go into financing new and needy projects. This would partially
reduce the pressure on the government to increase the investment ratio
in the economy by investing its own budgetary resources.
The third area in which the government should make changes is with regard
to foreign direct investment. Such investment is indeed required and can
play an important role if of an appropriate kind. But foreign investment,
which acquires large chunks of equity in firms catering to the domestic
market, uses these firms to market import-intensive branded products and
then takes out large amounts of foreign exchange in the form of technology
payments and dividends, needs to be regulated. The obvious adverse balance
of payments implications of the operations of these firms, implies that
to earn their profits they are draining the national pool of foreign exchange
resources which is then refurbished with capital in the form of hot money
that not merely drains out further foreign exchange but increases the
vulnerability of the system to financial crises. It is perfectly rational
as well as reasonable that foreign firms with equity holding above a certain
limit and extracting large technology payments should at the minimum earn
the foreign exchange that they propose to take out. Further, in terms
of emphasis, the effort should be to encourage foreign investment that
uses India as the outsourcing base for world market production, with positive
net employment and balance of payments effects. If outsourcing in software
and IT-enabled services is seen as such a major source of strength for
India, there is no reason why outsourcing in manufacturing should not
be seen as positive, and provided more privileges than foreign investment
catering primarily to the domestic market and regulated for balance of
payments reasons.
Finally, industrial policy should encourage small scale production with
both employment and linkage effects in mind. Protecting small scale production
with the employment objective in mind in a labour-surplus economy is not
a form of charitable intervention but rational economic policy. This was
recognized by Mahalanobis in his four-sector model which explicitly provided
for small and cottage production as a means of neutralizing the adverse
employment implications of investment in capital-intensive sectors. Such
protection would involve a rethink of excessive import liberalization
in sectors where small-scale production is viable, a restitution of measures
of protection like reservation of production and differential tariffs,
and a conscious direction of credit from the appropriate financial institutions
to meet investment and working capital needs.
These are some of the principal measures that the government can adopt
immediately to redress the distortions which indiscriminate liberalization
parading as "reform" has resulted in.
July 5, 2004. |