It
is obviously silly to push for austerity in the midst
of a recession, not just silly but cruel, since it
prolongs the pain of unemployment. The recession is
caused by a deficiency of aggregate demand. To overcome
it what is necessary is an increase in demand which
requires larger expenditure. Since private expenditure
on consumption is restrained in a recession by the
fact of unemployment and low income, since private
expenditure on investment is restrained by the fact
that when markets are not expanding capitalists have
little desire to increase their productive capacity,
and since the rest of the world's net expenditure
on the country's goods can increase only through a
shift of its demand from elsewhere, i.e. by a ''beggar-my-neighbour''
policy, which is no solution to the overall problem
and will invite retaliation from others, the sole
plausible way that the recession can be overcome is
through an increase in government expenditure, i.e.
through a fiscal stimulus. Austerity being the very
opposite of this will clearly worsen rather than improve
things.
But then why is there a push for austerity even in
the midst of a recession? The obvious answer is that
finance capital does not want a proactive State engaged
in demand management. If the State intervenes to fix
the level of activity in a capitalist economy, then
the ''state of confidence'' of the capitalists which
determines it otherwise, i.e. in the absence of such
State intervention, ceases to matter. This removes
any need to appease capitalists, to bolster their
''state of confidence'' through all kinds of inducements,
in the ''interests of society'', i.e. for the amelioration
of socially pressing problems like unemployment. Since
a prominent measure of appeasement of the capitalists
is to bolster the stock market, i.e. to act in conformity
with the caprices of finance capital, State intervention
in demand management through fiscal means is anathema
for finance capital, which therefore uses all the
resources at its command for preaching the virtues
of ''sound finance'' (i.e. of balancing budgets). The
demand for austerity in the midst of a recession,
i.e. for cutting down government expenditure in tandem
with the reduction in tax revenue that occurs in such
a period, is thus in keeping with the predilections
of finance capital. To effect this self-serving policy,
finance capital and its spokesmen advance the argument
that such austerity will actually overcome the recession,
which, as already mentioned, is a silly argument.
But just as ''false consciousness'' also has an element
of ''truth'', this patently silly argument for austerity
is not without a rationale within its own context.
And that context is the following. Since finance capital
believes, even if completely wrongly, that a fiscal
stimulus, in the form of a larger fiscal deficit,
is harmful for the economy, such a deficit may well
undermine the ''state of confidence'' of the financiers,
and hence, via its impact on the stock market and
other financial markets, of the capitalists as a whole.
Now, those who advocate a fiscal stimulus typically
have in mind a scenario where the revival of activity
following such a stimulus, brings about, in turn,
larger private investment and consumption expenditure,
such that the need for such a stimulus disappears
after a while; in other words they visualize the stimulus
necessarily as a temporary phenomenon, simply to get
the economy ''out of the woods'', after which ''business
as usual'' can take over. This, to repeat, is based
on the understanding that private investment picks
up once the level of activity picks up, that it simply
follows changes in the level of activity. But if the
act of stimulating the economy by the State also has
the effect of undermining the state of confidence
of the capitalists, then the revival of activity may
not be followed by the hoped-for revival of private
investment expenditure, or may at best be followed
by an anemic revival of such expenditure, in which
case the sustenance of the revival would require the
persistence of the fiscal stimulus. The fiscal stimulus
in short may not be the temporary phenomenon it is
supposed to be but may well turn out to be a more
durable affair.
This of course should not matter in itself. A fiscal
deficit which increases government borrowing, actually
puts the extra savings in the hands of the capitalists
that finance such borrowing. The extra government
borrowing in other words does not come out of any
pre-existing pool of private savings, i.e. it does
not cause any diversion of a pre-existing pool from
other uses to lending to the government.
This is a point so little understood, even by well-known
professional economists, that a word on it may be
in order. If the government decides to increase its
spending by 100 which it borrows, then demand increases
for domestic and foreign goods by that amount. This
raises domestic and foreign output, which increases
employment, and hence further increases demand and
output. This process goes on until an amount of additional
savings to the tune of 100 has been generated out
of this additional output in the hands of the domestic
private sector and of the rest of the world. In other
words, whatever the government borrows, generates
an equal amount of loanable resources in the hands
of the private sector and the rest of the world.
There should in principle therefore be no limits to
government borrowing. Besides, the government differs
from any private individual in the obvious sense that
it has the power to tax, so that the problem of repayment
of debt is also not a matter of concern. True, if
the tax-GDP ratio has to rise continuously to service
government debt, then beyond a point this debt may
become unsustainable (unless the government decides
to repudiate it); but even this problem is not of
any concern as long as the average interest rate on
government debt is less than the rate of growth of
the economy, which is not a particularly stringent
requirement. It follows then that even if the fiscal
stimulus becomes a durable affair, this in itself
should not be a matter of much concern.
But the real hurdle to the persistence of a fiscal
deficit is the loss of ''confidence'' of the financiers
in the government. This may sound ironical, and indeed
is, but no less real for that. The loanable resources
that any government fiscal deficit generates are borrowed
by the government through the intermediation of the
financiers. In other words, the loanable resources
generated in the hands of the domestic private sector
or of the rest of the world are held as deposits of
(or loans to) financial intermediaries like banks
which in turn buy government securities with them.
Even when the domestic private sector or the rest
of the world directly buy government securities (as
the Chinese are doing in the U.S.), their willingness
and eagerness to do so may still be influenced by
the opinions of the financiers about the government's
creditworthiness. Again, it is not a matter of whether
those opinions are ''right'' or ''wrong''; they count.
It follows that the loanable resources generated in
the event of government borrowing can flow back to
the government as borrowing (with which it can cover
the fiscal deficit) only if the financiers have ''confidence''
in the government. If because of the very fact of
the fiscal deficit, which they dislike anyway, they
lose this ''confidence'' in the government's creditworthiness
(this would happen especially if the fiscal deficit
persists), then the government cannot continue to
run fiscal deficits. This is exactly what has happened
in countries like Greece, and the S&P's downgrading
of the US government debt shows that it can happen
even to the United States.
It follows that State intervention through a fiscal
stimulus to overcome the recession must reckon with
the need to confront finance capital: the State must
be willing to run fiscal deficits not just as a temporary
phenomenon but even persistently, (since the ''state
of confidence'' of the capitalists may get undermined
by the very fact of fiscal deficits to a point where
private investment does not easily revive); and it
must also be willing to exert adequate control over
the financial system to ensure that public borrowing
is always financed, so that the State does not become
a prisoner to the caprices of financiers. The problem
with the economists in the United States who are arguing
for a fiscal stimulus is that they underplay the need
for the State to confront and control finance capital
as a complement to the strategy of a fiscal stimulus.
This is like arguing that one can eat ''one's cake
and have it too''. Notwithstanding their correct theoretical
position on what is immediately required to alleviate
unemployment, and their humane concern for the plight
of the unemployed, their argument is marred by this
contradiction. And the element of truth in those who
push for austerity, notwithstanding their silly theoretical
position and dubious ethical stance (since they are
acting in effect as spokesmen of finance capital and
are unconcerned about the cruelty that the system
is perpetrating on the unemployed), is that they are,
even if unconsciously, highlighting this contradiction.
To say, as many ''progressive'' American economists
do, that the only impediment to a fiscal stimulus,
which, let us agree, can alleviate the problem of
the recession, is the intellectual failure of its
opponents who are stuck with a wrong theory, is to
underestimate the systemic opposition to it; it is
to see the crisis as a mere policy failure, and not
as being embedded in the system itself. The opponents
of a fiscal stimulus no doubt have an intellectual
position that is shallow; but that position is the
outcome of a systemic reality that is deep. If the
crisis is embedded in the system itself then overcoming
it must entail some systemic change, in the absence
of which it would persist. The debate in America between
''austerity'' and ''stimulus'' alas is occurring within
a problematic that is inadequate. That problematic
posits that an economic crisis can be overcome through
a change in economic policy that is completely divorced
from any class realities, that the pursuit of ''right''
or ''wrong'' economic policy is a matter of intelligence
and intellectual ability and not class interests.
Of course it may be argued that for ''progressive economists''
in the U.S. to start talking of controlling and confronting
finance in a milieu that is otherwise so conservative,
would entail abandoning whatever residual hopes there
may be for a fiscal stimulus. But covering up ''truth''
is never an option that progressive opinion should
choose.
September
15, 2011.
|