It does not really need a crisis to
show us that our current development strategy is flawed. Even during the
previous boom, the pattern of growth in developing Asia had too many limitations,
paradoxes and inherent fragilities. Much was wrong with the global economic
boom that preceded the crisis. Everyone now knows that it was unsustainable,
based on speculative practices that were enabled and encouraged by financial
deregulation. But it also drew rapaciously and fecklessly on natural resources.
And it was deeply unequal. Contrary to general perception, most people
in the developing world, even within Asia, did not gain from that boom.
The financial bubble in the US attracted savings from across the world,
including from the poorest developing countries, so that for at least
five years the South transferred financial resources to the North. Developing
country governments opened up their markets to trade and finance, gave
up on monetary policy and pursued fiscally “correct” deflationary policies
that reduced public spending. So development projects remained incomplete
and citizens were deprived of the most essential socio-economic rights.
Despite popular perceptions, a net transfer of jobs from North to South
did not take place. In fact, industrial employment in the South barely
increased in the past decade, even in the “factory of the world” China.
Instead, technological change in manufacturing and the new services meant
that fewer workers could generate more output. Old jobs in the South were
lost or became precarious and the majority of new jobs were fragile, insecure
and low-paying, even in fast-growing China and India. The persistent agrarian
crisis in the developing world hurt peasant livelihoods and generated
global food problems. Rising inequality meant that the much-hyped growth
in emerging markets did not benefit most people, as profits soared but
wage shares of national income declined sharply.
Almost all Asian developing countries adopted an export-led growth model,
which in turn was associated with suppressing wage costs and domestic
consumption in order to remain internationally competitive and achieve
growing shares of world markets. This led to the peculiar situation of
rising savings rates and falling investment rates in many Asian countries,
and to the holding of international reserves that were then sought to
be placed in safe assets abroad. This is why globally the previous boom
was associated with the South (especially in developing Asia) subsidising
the North: through cheaper exports of goods and services, through net
capital flows from developing countries to the US in particular, through
flows of cheap labour in the form of short-term migration.
The current collapse in export markets has brought that process to a sharp
stop, but the point to note is that in any case such a strategy is unsustainable
beyond a point, especially when a number of relatively large economies
seek to use it at the same time. So not only was this a strategy that
bred and increased global inequality, it also sowed the seeds of its own
destruction by generating downward pressures on price because of increasing
competition as well as protectionist responses in the North.
In this boom, domestic demand tended to be profit-led, based on high and
growing profit shares in the economy and significant increases in the
income and consumption of newly globalised middle classes, which led to
bullish investment in certain non-tradeable sectors like financial assets
and real estate as well as in luxury goods and services. The patterns
of production and consumption that emerged meant that growth also involved
rapacious and ultimately destructive exploitation of nature and the environment.
The costs – in terms of excessive congestion, environmental pollution
and ecological degradation – are already being felt within our societies,
quite apart from the implications such expansion has on the forces generating
climate change.
There have been other negatives associated with the growth pattern. Within
developing Asia, it has led to an internal “brain drain” with adverse
implications for future innovation and productivity growth. The skewed
structure of incentives generated by the explosive growth of finance directed
the best young minds towards careers that promised quick rewards and large
material gains rather than painstaking but socially necessary research
and basic science. The impact of relocation of certain industries and
the associated requirement for skilled and semi-skilled labour did lead
to increased opportunities for educated employment, but it also led bright
young people to enter into work that is typically mechanical and does
not require much originality or creativity, with little opportunity to
develop their intellectual capacities in such jobs.
At the same time, crucial activities that are necessary for the economy
were inadequately rewarded. Farming in particular became increasingly
fraught with risk and subject to growing volatility and declining financial
viability, while non-farm work did not increase rapidly enough to absorb
the labour force even in the fastest growing economies of the region.
So the recent boom was not stable or inclusive, either across or within
countries. But unfortunately, the chances are that the slump will be only
too inclusive, forcing those who did not gain earlier to pay for the sins
of irresponsible and unregulated finance. As economies slow down, more
jobs will be lost and people, especially those in the developing world
who did not really gain from the boom, will face loss of livelihood and
deteriorating conditions of living.
It is now a cliché that every crisis is also an opportunity. Of
course, as the global financial crisis unfolds and creates downturns in
real economies everywhere, it is easy to see only the downside, as jobs
are lost, the value of financial savings of workers is wiped out, and
material insecurity becomes widespread. But in fact this global crisis
offers a greater opportunity than we have had for some time now, for the
Asian developing region’s citizens and their leaders to restructure economic
relations in a more democratic and sustainable way.
There are several necessary elements of this. Globally, everyone now recognises
the need to reform the international financial system, which has failed
to meet two obvious requirements: preventing instability and crises, and
transferring resources from richer to poorer economies. Not only have
we experienced much greater volatility and propensity to financial meltdown
across emerging markets and now even industrial countries, but even the
periods of economic expansion have been based on the global poor subsidising
the rich. Within national economies, this system has encouraged pro-cyclicality;
it has rendered national financial systems opaque and impossible to regulate;
it has encouraged bubbles and speculative fervour rather than real productive
investment for future growth; it has allowed for the proliferation of
parallel transactions through tax havens and loose domestic controls;
it has reduced the crucial developmental role of directed credit. Given
these problems, there is no alternative to systematic state regulation
and control of finance. Since private players will inevitably attempt
to circumvent regulation, the core of the financial system - banking -
must be protected, and this is only possible through social ownership.
Therefore, some degree of socialisation of banking (and not just socialisation
of the risks inherent in finance) is also inevitable. In developing countries
this is also important because it enables public control over the direction
of credit, without which no country has industrialised.
Second, the obsessively export-oriented model that has dominated the growth
strategy of the region for the past few decades needs to be reconsidered.
This is not a just a desirable shift – it has become a necessity given
the obvious fact that the US can no longer continue to be the engine of
world growth through increasing import demand in the near future. This
means that developing countries in general, and particularly those in
developing Asia that continue to rely on the US and the EU as their primary
export markets, must seek to redirect their exports to other countries
and most of all to redirect their economies towards more domestic demand.
This requires a shift towards wage-led and domestic demand led growth
particularly in the countries with economies large enough to sustain this
shift. This can happen not only through direct redistributive strategies
but also through public expenditure to provide more basic goods and services.
Third, this means that fiscal policy and public expenditure must be brought
back to centre stage. Clearly, fiscal stimulation is now essential in
both developed and developing countries, to cope with the adverse real
economy effects of the current crisis and prevent economic activity and
employment from falling. Fiscal expenditure is also required to undertake
and promote investment to manage the effects of climate change and promote
greener technologies. And public spending is crucial to advance the development
project in the South and fulfil the promise of achieving minimally acceptable
standards of living for everyone in the developing world. Social policy
– the public responsibility for meeting social and economic rights of
citizens – is not only desirable but also contributes positively to development.
Fourth, there have to be conscious attempts to reduce economic inequalities,
both between countries and within countries. We have clearly crossed the
limits of what is “acceptable” inequality in most societies, and future
policies will have to reverse this trend. Globally and nationally, we
have to recognise the need to reduce inequalities in income and wealth,
and also most significantly in the consumption of natural resources. This
is even more complicated than might be imagined, because unsustainable
patterns of production and consumption are now deeply entrenched in the
richer countries and are aspired to in developing countries. But many
millions of citizens of the developing world still have poor or inadequate
access to the most basic conditions of decent life, such as minimum physical
infrastructure including electricity and transport and communication links,
sanitation, health, nutrition and education. Ensuring universal provision
of this will inevitably require greater per capita use of natural resources
and more carbon-emitting production. So both sustainability and equity
require a reduction of the excessive resource use of the rich, especially
in developed countries, but also among the elites in the developing world.
This means that redistributive fiscal and other economic policies must
be specially oriented towards reducing inequalities of resource consumption,
globally and nationally. For example, within countries essential social
and developmental expenditure can be financed by taxes that penalise resource-wasteful
expenditure.
Fifth, then this requires new patterns of both demand and production.
This is why the present focus on developing new means of measuring genuine
progress, well-being and quality of life are so important. Quantitative
GDP growth targets, that still dominate the thinking of regional policy
makers, are not simply distracting from these more important goals, but
can even be counterproductive. For example, a chaotic, polluting and unpleasant
system of privatised urban transport involving many private vehicles and
over-congested roads actually generates more GDP than a safe, efficient
and affordable system of public transport that reduces vehicular congestion
and provides a pleasant living and working environment. So it is not enough
to talk about “cleaner, greener technologies” to produce goods that are
based on the old and now discredited pattern of consumption. Instead,
we must think creatively about such consumption itself, and work out which
goods and services are more necessary and desirable for our societies.
Sixth, this cannot be left to market forces, since the international demonstration
effect and the power of advertising will continue to create undesirable
wants and unsustainable consumption and production. But public intervention
in the market cannot be knee-jerk responses to constantly changing short-term
conditions. Instead, planning – not in the sense of the detailed planning
that destroyed the reputation of command regimes, but strategic thinking
about the social requirements and goals for the future – is absolutely
essential. Fiscal and monetary policies, as well as other forms of intervention,
will have to be used to redirect consumption and production towards these
social goals, to bring about such shifts in socially created aspirations
and material wants, and to reorganise economic life to be less rapacious
and more sustainable.
This is particularly important for quality of life in urban areas: the
high rates of urbanisation in developing Asia mean that within two decades
more than half our population will live in urban areas. Yet, because we
still do not plan for the future to make our cities pleasant or even liveable
for most residents, we tend to create urban monstrosities of congestion,
inequality and insecurity.
Seventh, since state involvement in economic activity is now an imperative,
we should be thinking of ways to make such involvement more democratic
and accountable within our countries and internationally. Large amounts
of public money will used for financial bailouts and to provide fiscal
stimuli, and how this is done will have huge implications for distribution,
access to resources and living conditions of the ordinary people whose
taxes will be paying for this. So it is essential that we design the global
economic architecture to function more democratically. And it is even
more important that states across the world and within developing Asia,
when formulating and implementing economic policies, are more open and
responsive to the needs of the majority of their citizens.
Finally, we need an international economic framework that supports all
this, which means more than just that capital flows must be controlled
and regulated so that they do not destabilise any of these strategies.
The global institutions that form the organising framework for international
trade, investment and production decisions also need to change and become
not just more democratic in structure but more genuinely democratic and
people-oriented in spirit, intent and functioning. Financing for development
and conservation of global resources must become the top priorities of
the global economic institutions, which means in turn that they cannot
continue to base their approach on a completely discredited and unbalanced
economic model.
September
15, 2009.
|