Financial
crises bring out all sorts of worms from cupboards.
Mostly, these reflect ineptitude, irresponsibility
and unrestrained greed, which are usually responsible
for having created the internal conditions for the
crisis, even if there could be other proximate or
external factors that are associated with the crisis.
But the strategies of dealing with any crisis have
to confront another huge problem, one which could
even lead to future financial crises: that of moral
hazard.
The Palgrave Dictionary of Economics defines moral
hazard as “actions of economic agents in maximising
their own utility to the detriment of others, in situations
where they do not bear the full consequences”. In
financial markets, these problems are especially rife
because such markets are anyway characterised by imperfect
and asymmetric information among those participating
in the markets.
The moral hazard associated with any financial bailout
results from the fact that a bailout implicitly condones
the earlier behaviour that led to the crisis of a
particular institution. Typically, markets are supposed
to reward “good” behaviour and punish those participants
who get it wrong. And presumably those who believe
in “free market principles” and in the unfettered
operations of the markets should also believe in its
disciplining powers.
But when the crisis hits, the shouts for bailout and
immediate rescue by the state usually come loudest
from precisely those who had earlier championed deregulation
and freedom from all restriction for the markets.
This has been very marked in the current crisis hitting
the US economy, reflected in the failure of major
mortgage institutions, insurance companies and Wall
Street banks.
The arguments for bailout are related either to the
domino effect - the possibility of the failure of
a particular institution leading to a general crisis
of confidence attacking the entire financial system
and rendering it unviable - or to the perception that
some institutions are too large and too deeply entrenched
in the financial structure, such that too many innocent
people, such as small depositors, pensioners and the
like, would be adversely affected.
It is this latter perception that has apparently led
to the recent decisions of the US Federal Reserve
that have effectively bailed out several major financial
institutions in the past few months, beginning with
providing a dowry for the failing bank Bear Stearns
in its shotgun marriage with JP Morgan, and then going
on to protect and then effectively nationalise the
mortgage holding agencies Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae.
Now, with the collapse of Lehmann Brothers, the looming
problems of the world’s largest insurance company
American International Group and as more large Wall
Street banks and finance institutions reveal the full
extent of the problems that they have accumulated
in the latest housing finance boom, the issue of more
and possibly even bigger bailouts is likely to become
more pressing.
Each of these huge bailouts is being presented as
a once-off, inevitable move designed to save the system.
Alan Greenspan, the former Chairman of the US Federal
Reserve, whose easy money policies were strongly implicated
in creating the speculative bubble that has now collapsed,
has stoutly defended these bailouts and suggested
that more may be necessary. In a recent interview
he is said to have declared: “This is a once-in-a-half-century,
probably once-in-a-century type of event. I think
the argument has got to be that there are certain
types of institutions which are so fundamental to
the functioning of the movement of savings into real
investment in an economy that on very rare occasions
— and this is one of them — it’s desirable to prevent
them from liquidating in a sharply disruptive manner.”
Forget, for a moment, whether this argument is correct,
or even whether it will actually be successful in
preventing a wider financial collapse. Consider instead
what sort of signal is sent to those who headed the
institutions that are being bailed out. The really
great moral hazard in the financial system today is
not just related to the bailout of the institutions:
it is even stronger among those who are in charge
and should be themselves directly paying the price
for taking wrong and irresponsible decisions.
Instead, financial markets are now so structured that
those running the institutions that collapse typically
walk off from the debris of the crisis not only without
paying any price, but after substantially enriching
themselves further. Consider, for example, Lehmann
Brothers, the major Wall Street bank which has collapsed
essentially because it went on a completely unsustainable
borrowing and lending spree, buying assets with as
little of its own money as possible and without proper
due diligence or prudential concern.
Now that the bank has collapsed, its 26,000 employees
will lose their jobs, and most of them are unlikely
to find new jobs easily in the current market context.
Since they held 25 per cent of the bank’s stock as
employee stock options, much of their savings is also
now valueless.
But the Chief Executive Office of Lehmann Brothers,
the man who was at the helm of affairs during all
the period of its completely irresponsible behaviour,
last year received a pay packet of more than $40 million.
According to the terms of his contract, if he is terminated
he will apparently receive more than $63 million as
part of his golden handshake. Since the much-publicised
jail terms awarded to some of the Enron managers in
the early part of the decade, CEOs of finance companies
and banks have also grown more savvy in protecting
themselves, ensuring that the writing in their contracts
provides for the absence of any personal liability
in the event of failure.
And the compensation of those in charge in the financial
sector is increasingly divorced from any relation
to the actual effects of their management. According
to a recent report in the Financial Times, compensation
for major executives of the seven largest US banks
amounted to more than $95 billion over the past three
years, even as the same banks recorded around $500
billion in losses.
Clearly, therefore, the issue of moral hazard cannot
be dealt with only in terms of faceless institutions
that are being rescued with taxpayers’ money. There
are individuals – in fact, a relatively small number
of individuals - who were enriched by the boom, who
were able to manipulate government policies, the media
and the gullible public to ensure the creation and
prolongation of what was always a speculative bubble
that would inevitably end. And these individuals also
appear to have rigged the system to ensure that they
are protected from the adverse fallout when the bubble
finally bursts.
Of course, what is happening in US capitalism today
is only a repeat the pattern of the financial crises
that spread across the developing world in the 1990s
and early 2000s. In all those cases, those who were
responsible for the policies and financial actions
that created the crisis, and who were the major beneficiaries
of the preceding boom, did not pay the costs of the
crises. These costs were borne by workers who lost
their jobs directly because of the crisis, as well
as those who were then affected by the stabilisation
measures imposed to control the crisis, including
small businesses that collapsed because of the high
interest rate-tight money regime that is a typical
post-crisis response.
Because those responsible for the crisis do not have
to pay for it, they have no compunctions in once again
creating the same conditions – and in fact that is
what is happening now in many of the formerly crisis-ridden
emerging markets.
Now it is in the US that we see how the agents of
irresponsible and predatory finance survive and even
prosper as everyone else goes under. So now the executives
are laughing all the way from the bank.
September
29 , 2008.
|