When Vietnam
signed a bilateral trade agreement with the US in 2000 with huge optimism
on the Vietnamese side, probably non one had seriously considered the
possibility that trade between these countries had the chance of becoming
less free in the years to come. This possibility was realized in July
this year, when the US Department of Commerce and the International Trade
Commission agreed to slap anti-dumping duties of up to 64% on Vietnam
exports of catfish to America on the grounds of dumping. This puts in
jeopardy the livelihood of a large number of catfish farmers in the Mekong
Delta in Vietnam. More important, this casts a cloud over Vietnam's huge
shrimp exports to America, exports that a much larger chunk of the Vietnamese
population is dependent on.
Vietnam had been exporting catfish even before 1995, when the official
embargo on Vietnamese exports was lifted by the US. However, the tremendous
spurt in exports came in 1999 when raw seafood tariffs dropped to zero.
At present, Vietnam exports some 18.3 million kilos of Catfish to the
US, which is valued at 55.1 million $US (2002). The value of exports has
been increasing at the amazing annual rate of 60.21% between 1999 and
2002. The volume of exports shows an even higher growth rate of 77% between
1999 and 2002. The change, which had started to take place from 1999,
shows an incredible increase of over 160% per cent in 2000 when compared
to the 1999 level of trade volume. The value of exports too showed a remarkable,
though lesser, increase of 123.9 % between 1999 and 2000. This trend has
evidently continued since Vietnam's exports have been boosted by a demand
for its tasty, and cheap catfish.
Since tariffs dropped to zero, Vietnam
had been able to export at its normal price, which comes out to be much
cheaper than its American counterpart. This is because Vietnam has the
advantage of cheap labour and other inputs. Raising fish in free flowing
water has the dual advantages of first, producing more tasty fish, and
second, producing fish at much cheaper rates compared to American Catfish
which uses more expensive groundwater. The American Catfish Farmers had
been protesting that Vietnamese Catfish was not produced under hygienic
conditions according to international standards. However, inspection by
the department of Commerce had clearly revealed that this was not indeed
the case. Vietnamese catfish is produced to international standards, and
most of the fish-feed are supplied by an American company called Cargill.
Catfish: To be or not to be
Vietnam's gradually larger presence in the Catfish market soon started
to spell trouble for the 590 million dollars US domestic catfish industry
that is mainly located in Arkansas, Mississippi and a few other southern
states. The trouble had been brewing for some time and a foreboding about
the final pro-protection judgement emerged in 2002 itself, when the Department
of Commerce in the US, in response to a litigation suit filed by the catfish
industry located in the south of US, prevented the Vietnamese catfish
from being called catfish at all. More specifically, the catfish Farmers
of America (CFA) lobbied the Congress to include language in the 2002
Agriculture Appropriations Act that specifically barred Vietnamese exporters
from labeling their fish as catfish. Their argument was that only catfish
of the species 'Ictalurus Punctatus', obviously cultivated by CFA, could
be called catfish. The species cultivated by Vietnam, 'Pangasius', has
now been banned by the American Farm Security Act of 2002.
Vietnamese catfish are now labeled Basa and Tra, which are the local names
for the subspecies. Given the fact that there are actually 2,500 subspecies
in the catfish family, which includes both the American and the Vietnamese
varieties, it was not clear why American Congress believed their farmers
have some intrinsic right to the name catfish that is ranked above the
rights of Vietnamese catfish farmers. But in a world where bigger fish
eats smaller fish, it was not surprising that Vietnamese farmers were
forced to swallow this piece of protectionism and hope for the best. As
it turned out, the demand for Vietnamese catfish, after initially suffering
a decline, picked up again. This was despite active campaigning by the
CFA against it.
Though Vietnam increased its sales drastically since 1999, it had occupied
less than 4% of the total catfish market in America over this period.
However, the bone of contention was the export of frozen Basa and Tra
fillet, which had occupied about 20% of the domestic market in the US.
The American producers are facing competition from Vietnam, the only other
big producer of catfish in the world, in other markets like the EU, Australia
and Japan as well. So it was getting more and more urgent for them to
protect their domestic market.
Anti Dumping: no hope for a non-market economy
The American products continued to suffer from stiff Vietnamese competition.
This made the CFA, think of other measures to escape from it. The next
best method was to suggest a re-course to the provision of anti-dumping
in the WTO rules and push for anti dumping/countervailing tariffs against
Vietnamese catfish. However, it was difficult to prove that the Vietnamese
catfish industry was receiving government subsidies or that the producing/exporting
units were undercutting their export price, which was necessary for proving
that dumping was taking place.
This made it imperative for the CFA to chose another line of offense.
Vietnam, given its historical background, lay vulnerable in one particular
area – its market economy status. It was, as it turned out, easy for the
CFA to argue that Vietnam is a 'non-market' economy. This clause in the
WTO rules, basically suggests that any economy that falls under this category
cannot claim to have competitive market prices. More specifically, their
prices may include an involuntary subsidization given the fact that input
prices (for example of labour) may not be competitively determined.
In this case, the price level of some other market economy, which has
a close resemblance to the non-market economy in question, is used as
a surrogate or proxy for determining whether prices at which products
were offered for sale by the non-market economy, are competitive or not.
This means for example, that for calculating Vietnam's competitive price
level (prices that would have prevailed under a market economy) prices
in some other country that produces similar products under similar conditions
would be used as indicators. Anti-dumping measures could be resorted to
if it was found that these proxy prices (adjusted according to other supply
conditions in Vietnam) reigned above the actual non-market economy prices
offered by Vietnam.
After determined petitioning by CFA and individual American catfish farmers,
the Department of Commerce's import administration determined on November
2002 that Vietnam was to be treated as a non-market economy (effective
from July 1, 2001) under the U.S. antidumping and countervailing duty
laws. To quote from the report, "while Vietnam has made significant
progress on a number of reforms, the Department's analysis indicates that
Vietnam has not yet made the transition to a market economy. Until revoked,
Vietnam's non-market economy status will apply to all future administrative
proceedings covering periods of investigation or review that fall after
the effective date of this decision".
This left the way open for finding a 'suitable' proxy. The Department
of Commerce (DoC) chose to pick India and Bangladesh as surrogate economies
for comparing catfish price levels. The DoC, found the price levels in
these countries much higher than Vietnam levels. Despite protests by the
Vietnamese Association of Seafood Exporters and Producers (VASEP), the
Department of Commerce (DoC) concluded in its preliminary order on January
27th, 2003 that " Vietnamese producers/exporters have made sales
to U.S. customers at less than fair value" and recommended the slapping
of anti-dumping duties on all major producers' products of fish fillets
. They calculated anti dumping margins ranging from 37.94 % (Vinh Hoan
Company) and 63.88% (Vietnam-wide). Subject to a final recommendation
by the DoC, and its approval by the US International Trade Commission
(ITC), America was all set to slap huge anti dumping duties on Vietmnam's
catfish fillet.
Preliminary Antidumping Margins Found by DOC
|
Company |
Margins |
Agifish |
61.88% |
Cataco |
41.06% |
Nam Viet |
37.94% |
Respondents who
voluntarily
submitted Section A responses
|
49.16% |
Vietnam-Wide |
63.88% |
Source:
Fact sheet on Preliminary determination in the Anti-dumping
Duty Investigation of Certain Frozen Fish Fillets from
Vietnam, Department of Commerce, USA, 27th January 2003. |
|
The subsequent final recommendation by
Doc on 17th June, upheld more or less its previous recommendation that
Vietnam had been selling its Catfish 'at less than fair value'. Taking
Bangladesh as the surrogate country, the report suggested anti dumping
duties to the tune of 64% be imposed on Vietnam-wide catfish products
with immediate effect. In case of some particular companies that had argued
various critical circumstances, DoC made certain exceptions and applied
different margins, some lower compared to the previous margins calculated
by the preliminary findings. According to this final determination the
Vietnam-wide rate of an incredibly high 63.88% applied to all entries
of the merchandise under investigation except for entries from Agifish,
Vinh Hoan, Nam Viet, CATACO, Afiex, Cafatex, Da Nang, Mekonimex, QVD,
Viet Hai and Vinh Long.
Final
Weighted Average Dumping Margins on Certain
Frozen Fish Fillets from Vietnam |
Producer
/ Manufacturer / Exporter |
Weighted-Average
Margin (%) |
Agifish |
44.76 |
Vinh
Hoan |
36.84 |
Nam
Viet |
52.90 |
Cataco
|
44.66 |
Afiex
|
44.66 |
Cafatex |
44.66 |
Da
Nang |
44.66 |
Mekonimex |
44.66 |
QVD |
44.66 |
Viet
Hai |
44.66 |
Vinh
Long |
44.66 |
Vietnam
Wide Rate |
63.88 |
|
|
Source:
Notice of Final Antidumping Duty Determination of Sales
at
Less Than Fair Value and Affirmative Critical Circumstances:
Certain
Frozen Fish Fillets from the Socialist Republic of Vietnam,
US Department of Commerce, June 17th, 2003 |
|
The ITC, the highest authority within
the US government on international trade issues, subsequently approved
this final determination on July 23rd, 2003. Since domestic legislation
on anti dumping or protectionist laws regulating product standard rules
overrides bilateral trade agreements, the BTA between the two countries
is unable to give any reprieve or confer any free trade advantages to
Vietnam in this case. This however, puts into question the usefulness
of such bilateral trade pacts between two countries that is supposed to
offer mutual benefits to the signatories. If worst comes to worst, it
might start off a trade war between the two. However in that eventuality,
as is the fate of developing countries, Vietnam has much more to lose
than its 'free-trade' partner.
Throughout the process, there were many protests by VASEP to the charges.
The first of these was that Vietnam should not be considered a non-market
economy. More importantly, Indian and Bangladesh prices do not properly
reflect the price situation in Vietnam. Even more unfair, pointed out
VASEP, was the fact that DoC used retail prices as a surrogate for wholesale
prices in Vietnam. In addition, since the Vietnamese farmers were using
American produced fish feed, that component of costs, a major one, could
hardly be underestimated. Add to that the fact that no company in Vietnam
nor the Vietnamese government was in the financial position to be able
to subsidize their exports, either for a significant amount of time or
a major quantity of products.
VASEP denounced the decision on catfish, saying it showed how "a
small group of fillet breeders in some southern states of the U.S. can
put pressure on American authorities" to ignore the principles of
competition and free trade it preaches worldwide. But this did not change
the decision of the DoC or the ITC. However, apparently the ITC did find
that some miscalculation had taken place in calculation of the 63.88%
margin and will probably re-calculate the dumping margin. But this is
likely to be a minor change in the duty figure(s) and not a major shift
in policy.
Shrimps: Another Victim in the Wings?
This is just the beginning of Vietnam's worries. Further problems plague
the seafood industry, the third highest export, in Vietnam. After the
successful campaign against Vietnamese catfish, shrimps seem the obvious
next target. US Shrimpers, especially from the Louisiana state that contributes
40% of the total shrimp production of the country, are all set to follow
the example of catfish. They claim that pond raised cheap shrimp from
Vietnam and other Asian and Latin American countries are flooding the
American market and driving shrimp prices to the floor. The tentative
list of countries to be targeted comprise of 16 countries including Brazil,
China, Ecuador, India, Thailand and Vietnam.
For Vietnam, this would bring even deeper trouble than the catfish tariffs.
Shrimp is the third highest export after crude oil and textiles and contributes
the highest share of its seafood exports. The US is also its largest market
as figures for 2002 show. Valued at 467 million US$, exports to the US
accounts for 48% of Vietnamese seafood exports. A huge number of farmers
in Vietnam are dependent on shrimp production and exports. It affects
the whole of the country rather than a specific region as in the case
of catfish. The fact that Vietnam has already been tagged a non-market
economy, makes it even more vulnerable compared to other countries in
the 'offenders' list. Further, being poor and small, its ability to defend
itself is much lower compared to countries like Brazil, China and India.
In the case of shrimp, however, there are two factors that Vietnam might
be able to make use of. First, the issue is much larger here and involves
many big countries in the developing world. Therefore, any protectionist
move on part of the US may land this dispute before the WTO. Even though
Vietnam is not yet a member of WTO, if the US is prevented from imposing
anti dumping tariffs on its member countries it should lose the moral
justification to carry forward a similar anti dumping suit against Vietnam.
However, the record of US morals, especially in trade negotiations, has
not been very strong. But there is another more material problem that
may arise for the US shrimp farmers. Since shrimp has a huge market in
America, slapping anti dumping duties that raise the price of shrimps
in the American domestic market may urge the large consumer base to actively
oppose any such attempts. This should be a matter of some concern for
the Department of Commerce.
Conclusion
The issue now affects the very poor catfish farmers of Vietnam in the
Mekong Delta and may in future affect the whole country. Fish farmers
in Vietnam are generally poor and operate on a very small scale. Apart
from desperately needing good sales for making ends meet, many have the
additional problem of paying off old production debts. Many poor farmers
had already mortgaged their land for buying fish cages. Shrimp farmers
are also heavily indebted after investing in drenches and ponds. In addition,
most of the seafood farmers are based in the poorest parts of the country,
where agriculture is not very productive given high soil salinity and
frequent flooding of agricultural land.
The protectionist antics of a country that prides itself on pushing trade
openness has unfairly robbed Vietnam's seafood farmers of the opportunity
to come out of indebtedness and make a decent living on the basis of hard
work. It also robs them of the advantage to make profitable use of their
natural resources. In addition, this is one of only a few cases where
low labour costs (and low opportunity cost of labour) can actually confer
certain advantages, at least in part, to the poor in developing economies.
This is so because the farmers themselves are very poor and also use a
lot of family labour. But this is evidently not so in a system of free
trade that is propagated by the US. Moreover, the fact that the Byrd amendment
of US law, entitles companies that initiate such anti-dumping legal suits
to revenues from such anti-dumping duties, is a further affront to the
poor farmers in Vietnam. By a WTO ruling, this amendment is to be repealed
but it would still be in effect till the end of 2003. So the American
farmers are still set to make an additional monetary gain from these duties.
Under the circumstances, Vietnam has no choice but to go on with its seafood
production, diversify both its export products and markets, cross its
fingers and hope for the best! It is an irony that such protectionism
has come from the US whereas the US and the EU are the very powers that
have been intent on prizing open developing economies to free trade. The
US has clearly shown that free trade for the powerful is the freedom to
use every backdoor tactic to ensure that trade is protected according
to the dictates of their own interests.
|