If
time lags matter, news of the dollar’s demise as the
world’s principal reserve currency is grossly exaggerated.
That prediction has been periodically heard at least
since the early 1970s when the United States brought
the Bretton Woods arrangement to an end by breaking
the link between dollar and gold. As is obvious, whatever
else may be said of the role of the US in the world
system, this expectation of the dollar’s displacement
as the currency that is as good as gold has not materialised.
This, however, is not to say that the dollar fulfils
its role adequately or even satisfactorily. Not surprisingly,
with the strength of the US economy once again in
question, the dollar has begun to slide. Between the
low of 1.2932 to the dollar it touched on 21 April
2009 and its value at the end of September 2009 the
euro had appreciated by 13 per cent vis-a-vis the
dollar. This (and other similar tendencies) has triggered
predictions of the demise of the dollar as lead currency.
Should and will a new currency replace the dollar
as the paper that is treated as good as gold?
There is a noteworthy feature of the debate sparked
by the revival of interest in the question of the
dollar’s worthiness as a reserve currency. Most participants
in the debate who argue that it is time for the dollar
to go, are not basing their argument on the greater
strength of an alternative currency (like the euro,
the yen or the Chinese RMB) which should take the
dollar’s place. Rather, the most popular alternative
is the IMF’s Special Drawing Right (SDR) which is
more a unit of account than a currency and whose value
is itself linked to that of a weighted basket of four
major currencies. There are three implications here.
First, even when the weakness of the US and the dollar
is accepted, the case is not that the dollar should
be completely displaced, since even in the basket
that constitutes the SDR the dollar commands an influential
role. Second, there is no other country or currency
that is at present seen as being capable of taking
the place of the US and its dollar at least in the
near future. And third, the search is not for a currency
that can be used with confidence as a medium for international
exchange, but for a derivative asset that investors
can hold without fear of a substantial fall in its
value when exchange rates fluctuate, because its value
is defined in terms of and is stable relative to a
basket of currencies.
It should be clear that in the absence of another
currency that can play a similar role in the world
economy, rhetoric alone will not end dollar hegemony.
The question, therefore, is whether the SDR can serve
as an actual currency or focus on the SDR is diverting
attention from alternative ‘real’ currencies. It must
be noted that early expectations of the displacement
of the dollar came with the birth of the euro in January
1, 1999 and the irrevocable fixing of the exchange
rates between the then member countries of the European
Union. The idea that the euro was an alternative to
the dollar came from the evidence that after a brief
period of stability and then depreciation of the euro
relative to the dollar, from the end of 2000 that
currency appreciated from close to $0.8 to the euro
to $1.6 to the euro in April 2008. And then, after
a further period of depreciation to around $1.25 to
the euro in November 2008, the euro has been on average
appreciating once again to reach $1.5 in September
2009.
There are two ways in which to view this relative
decline in the dollar’s value. The first is to see
it as a gradual depreciation of the dollar as part
of an effort to correct for the loss of export competitiveness
of the US. The second is to see it as a challenge
posed to the dollar’s supremacy by the new currency.
The supporting evidence to back the second of these
propositions is difficult to come by. Consider for
example the euro’s role in international transactions.
By September 2006, 30 per cent of outstanding international
securities were denominated in euros as compared with
around 20 per cent in 1999. But this was not because
of any significant decline of the dollar’s role in
this area, since its share had fallen from just around
one half to 46 per cent. In foreign exchange markets,
the euro’s share had remained stable at around 20
per cent of all transactions, compared with the dollar’s
44 per cent. And, finally, the euro accounted for
a stable 25 per cent of the holding of foreign exchange
reserves by countries that reported the composition
of their foreign exchange reserves. All in all, therefore,
it appears that the euro was not being displaced by
the dollar as the major reserve currency.
This is not surprising given the fact that the euro
is not the currency of a single national political
formation with the backing of a single powerful state.
Though monetary policy in these countries is harmonised
through the European Central Bank, which sets interest
rates for all, there is considerable fiscal policy
independence (despite the Growth and Stability Pact)
of countries characterised by very different levels
of development. This does not inspire confidence in
the ability of the EU as a formation to be able to
influence as desired the value of the euro. And no
single state in this formation has the military strength
or activism to assert power and stabilise the value
of the currency when required.
Put simply, while there are some European nations
like Germany that are economically strong, though
less so than before unification, if we look at the
conditions which helped sustain the dollar’s role
as the reserve currency, this united formation of
still legally independent sovereign states falls short
of what seems to be the prerequisites for the euro
to displace the dollar as reserve currency.
The SDR as reserve
Besides the euro the other contender to taking on
the role of the world’s reserve currency is the SDR
or Special Drawing Right created by the IMF. The debate
over the SDR as an alternative currency gathered momentum
when in the aftermath of the 2008 global crisis the
governor of the People’s Bank of China, Zhou Xiaochuan
issued a call for replacing the dollar with the SDR
as reserve currency. There are, however, many hurdles
between this stated desire and the actual transformation
of the SDR into the world’s reserve.
Created in 1969, the SDR was initially seen as a
supplemental reserve which could help meet shortages
of the two then prevailing reserve assets: gold and
the dollar. The IMF issues credits of SDRs to its
member nations, which can be exchanged for freely
usable currencies when required. The value of the
SDR was initially set to be equivalent to an amount
in weight of gold (0.888671 grams) that was then also
equivalent to one U.S. dollar. After the collapse
of the Bretton Woods system in 1973, however, the
value of the SDR was reset relative to a weighted
basket of currencies, which today consist of the euro,
Japanese yen, pound sterling, and U.S. dollar, and
quoted in dollars calculated at the existing exchange
rates. The liquidity of the SDR is ensured through
voluntary trading arrangements under which members
and one prescribed holder have volunteered to buy
or sell SDRs within limits. Further, when required
the Fund can activate its “designation mechanism”,
under which members with strong external positions
and reserves of freely usable currencies are requested
to buy SDRs with those currencies from members facing
balance of payments difficulties. This arrangement
helps ensure the liquidity and the reserve asset character
of the SDR. So long as a country’s holdings of SDRs
equal its allocation, they are a costless and barren
asset. However, whenever a member’s SDR holdings exceeds
its allocation, it earns interest on the excess. On
the other hand, if a country holds fewer SDRs than
allocated to it, it pays interest on the shortfall.
The SDR interest rate is also based on a weighted
average of specified interest rates in the money markets
of the SDR basket currencies.
The volume of SDRs available in the system is the
result of mutually agreed allocations (determined
by the need for supplementary reserves) to members
in proportion to their quotas. Till recently the volume
of SDRs available was small. SDRs have been allocated
on four occasions. The first tanche, to the tune of
SDR 9.3 billion, was issued in annual installments
during 1970-72, immediately after the creation of
this asset in 1969. The second, for SDR 12.1 billion,
occurred during 1979–81, after the second oil shock.
The third, for an amount of SDR 161.2 billion, was
issued on August 28, 2009. And the fourth for SDR
21.4 billion took place on September 9, 2009. As a
result the total volume of SDRs in circulation has
reached SDR 204.1 billion or about $317 billion. As
can be noted an overwhelming proportion of the allocation
has occurred in the aftermath of the 2008 financial
crisis. But even now the quantum of these special
reserves is well short of volumes demanded by developing
countries.
Does the recent substantial increase in the amount
of SDR’s allocated herald its emergence as an alternative
to the dollar? There are two roles that the SDR can
play, which favour its acceptance as a reserve. First,
it can help reduce the exposure of countries to the
dollar, the value of which has been declining in recent
months because of the huge current account deficit
of the US, its legacy of indebtedness and the large
volume of dollars it is pumping into the system to
finance its post-crisis stimulus package. Second,
since its value is determined by a weighted basket
of four major currencies, the command over goods and
resources that its holder would have would be stable
and even advantageous.
There are, however, five immediate and obvious obstacles
to the SDR serving as the sole or even principal reserve.
First, the $317 billion worth of SDRs currently available
are distributed across countries and is a small proportion
of the global reserve holdings estimated at $6.7 trillion
at the end of 2008 and of the reserve holding of even
a single country like China. Since all countries would
if possible like to hold a part of their reserves
in SDRs, the fraction of this $317 billion that would
be available for trade against actual currencies would
be small, implying that even with recent increases
in allocations the SDR can only be a supplementary
reserve. Second, expansion of the volume of SDRs in
circulation requires agreement among countries that
hold at least 85 per cent of IMF quotas. With the
US alone having a 16.77 per cent vote share, as of
now it has a veto on any such decision. Whether it
will go along with the decision to deprive it of the
benefits of being the home of the reserve currency
is unclear. And even if it does, there could be others
with a combined vote share of 15 per cent-plus who
may not be willing to go along.
Third, since SDR issues are linked to quotas at
the IMF and those quotas do not any more reflect the
economic strength of members, the base distribution
of SDRs is not in proportion to the distribution of
reserve holdings across countries. Reaching SDRs to
those who would like to hold them depends on the willingness
of now “weaker” countries to sell. Fourth, since the
value of the SDR is linked to the value of four actual
currencies, the reason why a country seeking to diversify
its reserve should not hold those four currencies
(in proportion to their weights in the SDR’s value)
rather than the SDR itself is unclear. This would
also give countries flexibility in terms of the proportion
in which they hold these four currencies (which is
an advantage in a world of fluctuating exchange rates,
since weights of currencies constituting the SDR are
reviewed only with a considerable lag, currently of
five years). Finally, as of now SDRs can only be exchanged
in transactions between central banks and not in transactions
between the government and the private sector and
therefore in purely private sector transactions. This
depletes its currency-like nature in the real world.
It also reduces the likelihood that a significant
number of economic transactions would be denominated
in SDRs. While this could be corrected, such a correction
can throw up a host of additional problems. But this
has not prevented suggestions from some like of John
Lipsky, the IMF’s First Deputy Managing Director,
that the SDR can be used as the foundation to build
a new currency that would be “be delinked from other
currencies and issued by an international organization
with equivalent authority to a central bank in order
to become liquid enough to be used as a reserve.”
This presumes we have or can think of a single global
state, which as of now is not a possibility. In fact,
to the many difficulties associated with treating
the SDR as a normal currency must be added the fact
that, not being the national currency of any country,
the confidence in its ability to serve as a viable
reserve currency for the world and in the stability
of its cannot be generated by either the economic
or the military strength of a state that governs that
nation. Put all of these together and while the SDR
may be good as a supplementary reserve that aids diversification
of the composition of reserves of individual countries,
it as yet falls short of the requirements that a true
reserve currency must meet.
If despite this the SDR is the focus of attention
in the search for an alternative to the dollar, that
can only be because there is as yet no national currency
that can displace the dollar. While the dollar lacks
the legitimacy to serve as the world’s reserve, it
dominates because the time for its substitute is yet
to come.
October
21, 2009.
|