The
Economics award is usually the last of the Nobel Prizes
to be announced. Correctly so, for it was also the
last to be created - and strictly speaking is not
even a real Nobel Prize. The five original awards,
first given out in 1901 for Literature, Peace, Medicine/Physiology,
Physics and Chemistry, were intended by Alfred Nobel
to recognise contributions that enhanced the quality
of human life, through scientific advance, literary
creativity or efforts at bringing about peace.
The Economics Prize is not a prize of the Nobel Foundation;
rather, it was created in 1968 by the Central Bank
of Sweden as a “Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory
of Alfred Nobel”. However, it now has the same procedure
of selection by the Swedish Academy and the same cash
award presented at a similar ceremony as the Nobel
Prizes.
There have been recurrent doubts about whether it
conforms to the basic goals of the Prizes as envisaged
by the founder. Is Economics a science, on the same
lines as Physics or Chemistry? Does it unambiguously
contribute to human well-being, like peace or literature?
In any case, should Economics be privileged over other
branches of learning?
Peter Nobel, great-grandnephew of the founder and
human rights activist, famously argued that Alfred
Nobel would not have approved of such a prize, which
he termed as “a PR coup by economists to improve their
reputation... most often awarded to stock market speculators”.
Certainly the reputation of economists has needed
building up, not only in the wake of the global financial
crisis, but even before that. As much of mainstream
economics became obsessed with navel-gazing esoteric
models or theories designed to justify market liberalism,
the general public became relatively more alienated
from the activities of economists. In such a context,
the Nobel Prize has definitely been a useful tool
not only to proclaim the conceptual advances supposedly
made by “the dismal science” but also to encourage
certain types of economic analysis and research. So
its power extends beyond public recognition, altering
the very production of economic knowledge.
The early prizes generally honoured economists whose
work was already widely recognised. But even in the
first decade, the list of exceptions was probably
more impressive than that of the recipients, as great
economists like Michal Kalecki, Joan Robinson, Richard
Kahn, Nicholas Kaldor and Piero Sraffa were overlooked
in favour of lesser contributors. In the subsequent
period, while some recipients have been universally
recognised, the award has occasionally gone to economists
of relatively minor and sometimes absolutely questionable
achievement, whom others in the profession quickly
had to look up when the announcement was made.
The political effect of the Prize in the profession
has been undeniable. There has been overwhelming domination
of neo-classical economics, to the exclusion of alternative
streams of thought, with only a few nods in the direction
of broader and more socially embracing approaches.
This has encouraged more conservative approaches to
the subject in research and teaching.
Monetarist and free market approaches have been disproportionately
rewarded, often at crucial times. For example, the
1974 award to Friedrich von Hayek led to a resurgence
of interest in the Austrian School and made his book
“The Road to Serfdom” a bestseller. Two years later
the Prize went to Milton Friedman, making his extreme
form of monetarism academically respectable and even
leading to a conservative policy revolution. Economic
history in the turgid and restricting form of retrospective
econometrics was promoted by the 1993 award to Robert
Fogel and Douglass North, while rational expectations
theory was given a big boost by honouring Robert Lucas
in 1995.
The geographical distribution of the award both creates
and reflects power hierarchies in the discipline.
The Economics Prize has been awarded 40 times to 66
recipients, 42 of whom have been from the USA, while
50 were working in the USA at the time of the award.
The University of Chicago has 11 laureates, leading
to the joke about “the Stockholm-Chicago Express”.
This does not reflect the actual state of economic
knowledge so much as the biases and blindness of the
jury. In the history of the prize, only two persons
from developing countries have received it (Arthur
Lewis and Amartya Sen) and both worked in the US and
England. Only three economists with an interest in
the economics of developing countries – which is the
economic reality for around three quarters of the
world’s population – have received the award.
In recent years, the Prize has been focussed on financial
market behaviour. In 1997, the award went to two economists
– Robert Merton and Myron Scholes – who were supposed
to have discovered a method of valuing derivatives
that could reduce or eliminate risk in financial investment.
When the hedge fund that they ran (Long Term Capital
Management) went bust within the year and had to be
rescued by the US Fed, there was some embarrassment.
Perhaps to right this wrong, a few years later the
prize was given to economists George Akerlof and Joseph
Stiglitz, who had pointed to the imperfect functioning
of financial markets. The award last year to Paul
Krugman may also have indicated some bowing to changing
times.
So far, no woman has got the Economics Nobel. Apart
from obvious exclusions such as Joan Robinson, this
also reflects power hierarchies within the subject,
because women economists even in the US and UK tend
to be concentrated in the lower reaches of the academics
profession - as researchers and lecturers rather than
professors.
These imbalances will not be rectified easily. But
the Nobel Prize in economics may now be as much in
need of wider legitimacy as the economics profession
itself. It will be interesting to see if this is reflected
in the current year’s award.
October
10, 2009.
|