Despite
its second round passage, the collapse of the first-round
vote in the US Congress on a package to use $700 billion
of public money to bail out firms threatened by the
fall-out of the sub-prime crisis has two lessons.
First, that the White House, the Treasury and the
Federal Reserve, who were saying that intervention
was inevitable to avoid a financial meltdown, were
making the case for a specific kind of intervention
that favoured Wall Street but ignored Main Street.
Having made huge profits on speculation, Big Finance
wanted the State to pick up the losses when the bubble
burst. Second, it showed that whether the advocates
of neo-liberalism were willing to accept it or not,
this was the end of the neoliberal era, with the neoconservatives
deciding that there was no option other than bringing
the State back in. Their effort was to do so without
giving the State a role in regulating capital. The
collapse and subsequent adjustments to the bill indicates
that they have failed.
The final version of the Bill, which reflected a deal
between Democrat and Republican negotiators, included
some modifications of and additions to the outrageous
demands originally made by the U.S. administration
and the Federal Reserve. These changes were necessitated
by the reservations expressed by both Democrats and
Republicans pressured by criticism from their constituents
that the deal planned to use taxpayers’ money to bail
out financial players who profited at the expense
of the system.
Despite the modifications, this is a bailout deal
that was not warranted. It is indeed true that the
U.S. has in hand a serious financial crisis, whose
arrival was recognised rather late by a conservative
administration, which along with its predecessors
was responsible for adopting policies encouraging
the practices that led to the crisis. It waited until
the sub-prime mess precipitated a credit crunch, with
banks unwilling to lend for fear of being loaded with
more worthless financial assets. As a result, the
“toxic waste” consisting of mortgage-related or mortgage-backed
securities is threatening the viability of a range
of financial institutions and whole segments of the
financial system.
So, intervention by the state to stall a crisis, which,
in the words of Warren Buffet, could be “the biggest
financial meltdown in American history” was necessary
and unavoidable. Unfortunately, however, the bailout
in its current form does little to ensure that those
responsible for the crisis are penalised, does not
put in place regulatory institutions and conditions
that could pre-empt similar crises in the future,
and is, for a number of reasons, unlikely to deliver
a resolution of the crisis reflected in bankruptcies,
bailouts, acquisitions and mergers.
It is surprising, therefore, that Democrats, who dominate
Congress, while rejecting the request from a lame-duck
President for a blank cheque with a huge spending
limit and few conditions attached, backed the main
contours of the original draft Bill and acceded to
many of the demands of the George W. Bush administration.
One explanation is that this was an effort on the
part of the Democrats to show that they would not
use their majority to stall immediate intervention
when the system faces a crisis, even if that crisis
was of the Republicans’ making. Eventually, it was
the Republican caucus that stalled the administration’s
Bill in the first round, on the grounds that it violated
all the free-market principles that conservatives
claim to stand for. Many Republicans did not want
to be seen as endorsing the view that it was the market-friendly
push by past and current Republican administrations
that precipitated this crisis.
But many Democrats, too, are supporters of liberal
financial policies. Therefore, bipartisan support
for the Bill was in all probability reflective of
the recognition by both Democrats and Republicans
alike that unless something was done to stall the
unfolding crisis, a return to intense regulation was
inevitable.
Worthless Assets
But, in all probability, the only comprehensive plan
the Treasury had put on the table to resolve the crisis
will fail to deliver. What the plan does is give the
Treasury (and its private financial advisers, including
players who contributed to the crisis) the power to
buy not just the near-worthless or “impaired” mortgage-related
assets from financial institutions but also any other
assets from any other party so as to “unclog” their
balance sheets and get credit moving. Implicit in
this view is that there are two kinds of securities.
One kind consists of those that have lost value because
the mortgages or other loans they are backed with
are subject to defaults on payments, leading to foreclosures
in a market where the values of those assets are falling.
The second kind consists of those that have lost value
or whose value is unknown because the credit crunch
has frozen the market for these securities, leaving
them with no estimable market value. With some assets
being worthless and others being of unidentifiable
value, it is argued, the viability of many financial
firms is in question, depriving them of the funds
needed to keep their business going.
The Treasury view, backed by the Federal Reserve,
is that if financial institutions were relieved of
the first set of securities, their balance sheets
would improve and they would be in a position to resume
trading or lending and the values of the second set
of securities would automatically improve and stand
revealed, resulting in a further improvement in the
balance sheets of the institutions holding them. This,
it is argued, would return credit and asset markets
to normality, restore values of “unimpaired” or frozen
securities, and stop the wave of bankruptcies, state
takeovers, acquisitions and forced mergers that have
transformed the U.S.’ financial landscape over the
last month.
It would also, supposedly, restore the value of many
of the securities acquired by the government, allowing
it to sell them and recoup the taxpayers’ money that
was to be used to finance this bailout of institutions
that failed or are performing poorly because of lack
of due diligence and transparency, unsound and excessively
speculative financial practices or even sheer malpractice.
In a move aimed at indicating that the requirements
of taxpayers are being taken care of, the final draft
required the President to work out means to recover
any losses that would be incurred after five years
in the sale of assets acquired under the programme.
The problem is that the information available in the
Bill on the bailout is inadequate to answer a number
of questions. First, which would be the securities
that the government would buy out and to what extent?
The $700 billion figure was the limit set for acquisitions
of the troubled assets, whose total value has been
guesstimated at upwards of $3 trillion.
That figure would have been even higher had the Treasury
been given the discretion to add on any other assets
it considers worthy of similar support. It should
be expected that the money would be used to buy the
worst assets and “unclog” the system so that the less
impaired and frozen securities can find their value.
The private financial sector too would lobby for such
a move since the worst assets are the securities they
want off their books. This implies that the assumption
is that $700 billion is enough to clear the system
of these securities though the basis for that assumption
is by no means clear.
The second question that arises is the manner in which
prices of the securities to be acquired are set. The
bailout plan seeks to use market-based methods, including
reverse auctions in which sellers looking for a buyer
bid down the price at which they are willing to sell
their assets. Since the most impaired securities are
near worthless, their prices should be closer to zero
for every dollar worth of such assets in terms of
their accounting or par values. Setting them there
would also permit the government to acquire a substantial
volume of securities when seeking to unclog the system
or to even save a part of the taxpayers’ money it
is authorised to spend to achieve this objective.
The problem, however, is that if this were done, the
institutions that are selling these assets at near-zero
prices would have to take large write-downs onto their
balance sheets and reflect these losses. This would
undermine their viability and result in failure unless
they are recapitalised with an infusion of new funds,
as happened in the case of Washington Mutual, a troubled
mortgage bank that had to be seized by federal regulators,
shut down and then sold off to JPMorgan Chase &
Co. This is the largest bank failure in U.S. financial
history, yet the going price for Washington Mutual
was a mere $1.9 billion, with no payments to holders
of $30 billion in debt and preferred stock.
WaMu, as the institution is informally called, had
a troubled loan portfolio of $307 billion. JPMorgan
expects to write down about $31 billion of bad loans
and raise $8 billion in new capital to recapitalise
the bank and successfully integrate it into its own
operations. There are other instances where recapitalisation
is being ensured through an early sell out (Merrill
Lynch) or through a large infusion of capital, as
happened with Goldman Sachs, which is supported with
capital from Warren Buffet.
These experiences have two implications. First, they
show that recapitalisation is unavoidable when the
asset portfolios of troubled financial institutions
are restructured in the face of losses. Second, they
also indicate that as long as there are strong financial
institutions or investors who can take on the responsibility
of recapitalising weaker firms, the market is not
so frozen that they would not be able to mobilise
the requisite capital for the purpose. If, instead
of looking at options of this kind, the administration
chooses to buy up assets at low prices without recapitalisation,
it may be providing immediate support to beleaguered
financial institutions but not resolving the problem
that spreading bankruptcy is creating in the system.
One option would be for the government to buy the
assets at prices closer to par values on the grounds
that the resulting revival in financial markets would
render those prices, which may seem absurd in terms
of current conditions, sensible in the long run and
defensible from the taxpayer’s point of view. Figures
as high as 80 cents to the dollar are rumoured to
be in circulation. This would mean that financial
institutions would be able to take much smaller write-downs
and would not need significant recapitalisation. But
it also means that the Treasury may have run through
the $700 billion rather quickly, even before enough
of the “toxic waste” had been cleared.
In fact, many financial firms would be willing to
dump even some of their less impaired or good (but
frozen) assets at those prices, leaving the worst
assets in the system. If this is not to happen, the
administration should choose to buy the worst assets
at high prices even when better assets are available
at the same price. This could invite the criticism
that this is misuse of taxpayers’ money unless the
$700-billion limit is relaxed, making the whole process
open-ended and unsustainable. It is possibly for this
reason that Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson, an ex-Goldman
Sachs man, tried to protect himself and his successors
in the first of the drafts of the legislation that
was to define and authorise the scheme.
In the words of The New York Times, the original draft
gave the Treasury Secretary “the authority to buy
any assets from any financial institution at any price
that he deemed necessary to provide stability to the
financial markets”. The draft also asserted “that
neither the courts nor any administrative agency would
be allowed to question or review these decisions”.
The recovery scheme was based on the premise that
an appropriate set of bets could pull U.S. financial
markets back from the brink of disaster. So the person
placing those bets must be free of any fear that failure
would make him responsible for burning taxpayers’
money. Unfortunately, the chances of failure are substantial.
No Congress can hand over such powers without oversight,
which has been allowed for in the final law.
The problem was not that there were no better options.
One would have been to combine some state support
with market-mediated solutions, which would reduce
the cost to the taxpayer of a process of financial
restructuring. The JPMorgan Chase takeover of WaMu
showed that the latter was possible. Many other options
have also been offered and discussed.
Thus, James Galbraith, a Professor of Economics at
Austin Texas (and son of the well-known John Kenneth
Galbraith), suggested that since the large, purely
investment bank that is not subject to capital requirements
and is more leveraged is now non-existent (with the
closure of Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, the merger
of Merrill Lynch with Bank of America and the conversion
of Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley into bank-holding
companies), the task of managing the current financial
distress could have been given to the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation. It could have been offered
a substantial part of the $700 billion to insure deposits
even in excess of the currently specified $100,000,
foreclosing bank runs and attracting capital that
could help banks recapitalise themselves. Where matters
are more difficult, a part of the money could be directly
used for recapitalisation of the institutions concerned,
with share ownership going to the government.
Getting share ownership for the government when bailing
out banks was a strategy adopted by the Swedish government
after its banking crisis in 1992. It got banks to
write down losses, required shareholders as opposed
to taxpayers to carry much of the burden and offered
bailout funds in exchange for equity. Equity ownership
gave taxpayers the hope of some returns when distressed
assets were sold or when shares were sold after successful
restructuring.
There were some improvements in the final version
of the Bill, however. It recognised that if taxpayers’
money was being used, they should not merely be offered
the promise that this burden would be neutralised
when the government recoups the money through the
sale of acquired assets when market normality is restored,
but a stake in the banks they are bailing out so that
they can exercise both some supervision of the use
of their money as well as have the choice of retaining
an equity stake if these banks survive and recover.
It accepted the need to regulate and tax executive
compensation and severance packages in firms supported
by the government. And it provided for congressional
oversight, with the proviso that bailout financing
would be released in three stages, starting with an
initial $250 billion. Congress was to have the right
to vote to hold back a final tranche of $350 billion
if the funds were not being used effectively.
Finally, the bailout recognised the importance of
backing homeowners whose now-much-cheaper houses are
being foreclosed because they cannot keep to payments
commitments on mortgages that reflect the high values
of the property boom years and involve extremely high
interest payments. The Treasury, as owner of mortgages
it has bought up, can attempt to reduce foreclosures
by trimming the principal, cutting the interest rate
or increasing the payback period on mortgages. Besides
being fair in itself, the use of some of the money
to help homeowners retain their assets may have salutary
effects on consumption demand, which could limit the
collateral damage of this financial disaster on growth
and employment.
All this notwithstanding, this historically unprecedented
bailout was one that subsidised finance, underwrote
losses generated by market forces, and left most others
directly or indirectly affected by the excesses of
the mortgage-lending boom untouched. It is partly
to meet such criticism that the Bill provided for
the obtaining of compensation from banks and other
financial institutions after five years in case the
government loses money on the impaired securities
it purchases. This assumes that these banks will be
in a position to compensate the government even if
the securities that the latter took over are not performing
well. They probably will not be.
Thus, there are reasons to believe that the current
package in the Bill will fail to address the crisis
adequately and restore stability. Meanwhile, globally,
markets are in a state of collapse, partly driven
by the expectations generated by the scaremongering
used to push through the package. The danger is that
those threats may actually be realised.
October
10 , 2008.
|