In mid-July,
Alan Greenspan, chairman of the US Federal Reserve, while deposing before
a congressional committee, warned the Chinese authorities that they could
not continue to peg the renminbi to the US dollar, without adversely affecting
the functioning of their monetary system. This touching concern for and
gratuitous advice to the Chinese had, however, some background. Greenspan
was merely echoing the sentiment expressed by a wide circle of conservative
economists that the Chinese must float their currency, allow it to appreciate
and, hopefully, help remove what is being seen as the principal bottleneck
to the smooth adjustment of the unsustainable US balance of payments deficit.
China was, of course, only the front for a wide range of countries in
Asia, who were all seen as using a managed and “undervalued” currencies
to boost their exports. Around the same time that Greenspan was making
his case before the congressional committee, The Economist published an
article on the global economic strains being created by Asian governments
clinging to the dollar either by pegging their currencies or intervening
in markets to shore them up. That article reported the following: “UBS
reckons that all Asian currencies, except Indonesia’s are undervalued
against the dollar … The most undervalued are the yuan, yen, the Indian
rupee and the Taiwan Province of China and Singapore dollars; the least
undervalued are the ringgit, the Hong Kong dollar and the South Korean
won.”
The evidence to support this is of course limited. It lies in the fact
that while over the year ending September 3rd the euro has appreciated
against the dollar by about 9 per cent, many Asian currencies have either
been pegged to the dollar, appreciated by a much smaller percentage relative
to the dollar or even depreciated vis-à-vis the dollar.
To anyone who has been following the debate
on exchange rate regimes and exchange rate levels in developing countries,
this perception would appear to be a dramatic reversal of the mainstream,
conservative argument that had dominated the development dialogue for
the last three to four decades. Till recently, many of these countries
were being accused of pursuing inward looking policies, of being too interventionist
in their trade, exchange rate and financial sector policies, and, therefore,
of being characterized by “overvalued” exchange rates that concealed their
balance of payments weaknesses. An “overvalued” rate, by setting the domestic
currency equivalent of, say, a dollar at less than what would have been
the case in an equilibrium with free trade, is seen as making imports
cheaper and exports more expensive. This can be sustained in the short
run because trade restrictions do not result in a widening trade and current
account deficit. But in the medium term it seen as encouraging investments
in areas that do not exploit the comparative advantages of the country
concerned, leading to an inefficient and internationally uncompetitive
economic structure.
What was required, it was argued, was substantial liberalization of trade,
a shift to a more liberalized exchange rate regime, less intervention
all-round, and a greater degree of financial sector openness. Partly under
pressure from developed county governments and the international institutions
representing their interests, many of these countries have since put in
place such a regime.
Seen in this light, consistency and correctness are not requirements it
appears when defending the world’s only superpower. Nothing illustrates
this more than the effort on the part of leading economists, the IMF,
developed country governments and the international financial media to
hold the exchange rate policy in Asian countries, responsible for stalling
the “smooth adjustment” of external imbalances in the world system. The
biggest names have joined the fray to make the case: Alan Greenspan, chairman
of the US Federal Reserve, John Snow, US treasury secretary, and Kenneth
Rogoff, IMF chief economist.
The adoption of a liberalized economic regime in which output growth had
to be adjusted downwards to prevent current account difficulties and attract
foreign capital had its implications. It required governments to borrow
less to finance deficit spending, which often led to lower growth, lower
inflation and lower import demand. Combined with or independent of higher
export growth, these effects showed up in the form of reduced deficits
or surpluses on their external trade and current accounts. Since in many
cases the ‘chronic’ deflation that the regime change implied was accompanied
by large capital inflows after liberalization, there was a surplus of
foreign exchange in the system, which the central bank had to buy up in
order to prevent an appreciation in the value the nation’s currency. Currency
appreciation, by making exports more expensive and imports cheaper, could
have devastating effects on exports in the short run and generate new
balance of payments difficulties in the medium term. In fact, among the
reasons underlying the East Asian crises of the late 1990s was a process
of currency appreciation driven by export success on the one hand and
liberalized capital inflows on the other.
Faced with this prospect countries like China and India chose to adopt
a more cautious approach to economic liberalization and, especially with
regard to the exchange rate regime and to the liberalization of rules
governing capital flows into and out of the country. However, even limited
liberalization entailed providing relatively free access to foreign exchange
for permitted trade and current account transactions and the creation
of a market for foreign exchange in which the supply and demand for foreign
currencies did influence the value of the local currency relative to the
currencies of major trading partners. This made the task of managing the
exchange rate difficult. The larger the flow of foreign exchange because
of improved current account receipts (including remittances) and enhanced
inflows of capital (consequent to limited capital account liberalization),
the greater had to be the demand for foreign exchange if the local currency
was to remain stable. But given the context of extremely large flows (China)
and/or relatively low demand during the late 1990s due to deflation (India),
there was a tendency for supply to exceed demand, even if this did not
always reflect a strong trading position. As a result, to stabilize the
value of the currency the central banks in these countries were forced
to step in, purchase foreign currencies to stabilize the value of the
local currency, and build up additional foreign exchange reserves as a
consequence.
Different countries adopted different objectives with regard to the exchange
rate. China, for example, chose to make a stable exchange rate a prime
objective of policy and has frozen its exchange rate vis-à-vis
the dollar at renminbi 8.28 to the dollar since 1995. To its credit, it
stuck by this policy even during the Asian currency crisis, when the value
of currencies of its competitors like Thailand and Korea depreciated sharply.
This helped the effort to stabilize the currency collapse in those countries,
even if in the immediate short run it affected China’s trade adversely.
India too had adopted a relatively stable exchange rate regime right through
this period, allowing the rupee to move within a relatively narrow band
relative to a basket of currencies, and not just the dollar.
The net result is that most Asian countries – some that fell victim to
the late 1990s financial crises, like Korea, and those that did not, like
China and India – have accumulated large foreign exchange reserves (Chart
2). According to one estimate, Asia as a whole is sitting on a reserve
pile of more than $1600 billion. This was the inevitable consequence of
wanting to prevent autonomous capital flows that came in after liberalization
of foreign direct and portfolio investment rules from increasing exchange
rate volatility and threatening currency disruption due to a loss of investor
confidence. These reserves are indeed a drain on these systems, since
they involve substantial costs in the form of interest, dividend and repatriated
capital gains but had to be invested in secure and relatively liquid assets
which offered low returns. But that cost was the inevitable consequence
of opting for the deflation and the capital inflow that resulted from
the stabilization and adjustment strategy so assiduously promoted by the
US, the G-7, the IMF and the World Bank in developing countries the world
over. Unfortunately, the current account surpluses and the large reserves
that this sequence of events resulted in have now become the “tell-tale”
signs for arguing that the currencies in these countries are “under-“
not “overvalued” and therefore need to be revalued upwards.
For long, this episode of rising reserves
in till-recently poor countries appeared almost conspiratorial, because
these reserves were being invested in dollar denominated assets including
government securities in the US and played an important role in financing
the burgeoning current account deficit in the US (Chart 3). The choice
of US assets was, of course, determined by the facts that the dollar still
is the world’s reserve currency and the US the world’s sole superpower,
both of which engender confidence in American, dollar-denominated assets.
The direct benefit for the US was obvious. With America experiencing growth
without the needed competitiveness, that growth was accompanied by a widening
of the trade and current account deficits on its balance of payments.
Capital inflows into the US helped finance those deficits, without much
difficulty. For example, UBS estimates that in the second quarter of 2003,
the central banks in Japan and China bought $39 billion and $27 billion
of dollars respectively. If these are invested in American assets they
would finance close to 45 per cent of the estimated $147 billion US current
account deficit in that quarter. They indeed were. Central banks, mostly
from Asia, are estimated to have financed more than half of the US current
account deficit in the second quarter.
The indirect benefits of this arrangement
are even greater. For more than a decade now, the US has benefited from
a long period of buoyancy, so much so that it has accounted for 60 per
cent of cumulative world GDP growth since 1995. That buoyancy came not
because the US was the world’s most competitive nation in economic terms.
Rather, till the turn of the last decade growth was accounted for by a
private consumption and investment spending boom, spurred by the bubble
in US stock and bond markets (Chart 4) that substantially increased the
value of the savings accumulated by US households. The money market boom
was encouraged by the flight of capital from across the world to the safe
haven that dollar denominated assets were seen as providing. Investment
of reserves accumulated by the Asian countries was one important component
of that capital inflow. With the value of their savings invested in stocks
and securities inflated by the boom, consumers found confidence to spend.
To be sure, when the speculative boom
came to end in 2000, triggered in part by revelations of corporate fraud,
accounting scandals and conflicts of interest, this spur to growth was
substantially moderated. But the low interest rate regime adopted by the
Fed still encouraged debt-financed consumer spending. Together with the
return to deficit-financed spending by the American state (Chart 5), justified
by its nebulously defined war on terror, America is once again witnessing
buoyant output growth even if this has not improved the employment situation
significantly. In fact, 2.6 million manufacturing jobs have been lost
in the US since Bush assumed office in 2001.
The only threat to US buoyancy throughout
this period was the possible unsustainability of the widening current
account deficit in its balance of payments. But the boom was not aborted,
because the rest of the world appeared only too willing to finance those
deficits, even if at falling interest rates in some periods.
Unfortunately, few other countries benefited directly from this chain
of events. They did not because they did not have the military power to
create the required confidence in their currencies, even if sheer competitiveness
warranted a decline in the dollar. Some countries benefited indirectly:
China, for example, because of the export boom to the US; the UK because,
among other things, of a boom in services, including financial services.
But overall, to use a phrase popularized by former US Treasury secretary
Lawrence Summers, the world economy was flying on one engine.
Within the imperial order always fearful of a “hard landing”, this has
created two imperatives. First, in the medium term, the world needs other
supportive engines, which must be from within the developed economies.
Second, till that time, and even thereafter, US growth must be sustained.
The new discovery that Asian currencies, particularly the Chinese renminbi,
is under- and not overvalued, stems from the second of these two concerns.
With the US current account deficit expected to exceed 5 per cent this
year, there are few who are convinced that it would find investors who
would be confident enough to continue financing that deficit. This is
becoming clear from the fact that the share of the deficit financed by
central bank investments is rising, as private investors grow more cautious.
Thus, if the dollar is not to collapse, the US current account deficit
must be curtailed and reversed.
However, this cannot be ensured by curtailing US growth and therefore
the growth of US imports. It is necessary to boost exports, so that growth
can coexist with a reducing trade and current account surplus. This is
where China and the fact that it notched up a record $103 billion trade
surplus with the US last year comes in. Ignoring the fact that simultaneously
China had recorded a trade deficit of $75 billion with the rest of the
world, the surplus with the US is seen as a direct consequence of China’s
undervalued exchange rate, which has been pegged to the dollar since 1995
despite rising capital flows and reserves. Thus, the story goes, if China
revalues its currency vis-à-vis the dollar by anywhere between
15 and 40 per cent, depending on the advocate, China would absorb more
imports from and be able to export less to the US, correcting the trade
imbalance between the two countries.
But that is not all. If China revalues its currency, it is argued, Europe
would improve its competitiveness lost as a result of the appreciation
of the euro vis-à-vis the dollar and therefore the renminbi, allowing
it to register higher export growth. Further, China’s revaluation would
reduce the need to pressurize Japan to revalue the yen, despite its own
surpluses with the US and the high level of its reserves. This deals with
the danger that yen revaluation might abort the feeble recovery that Japan
is experiencing after a decade of stagnation. These benefits could possibly
yield the supportive engines needed to keep the world economy in flight.
In this assault on the less-developed nations, involving a complete reversal
of the argument regarding the currency regime in developing countries,
the US and its allies are finding strange supporters. Trade unions and
manufacturing companies located in the US who have experienced job and
market losses have joined the chorus through organizations such as “The
Coalition for a Sound Dollar”. They are even threatening to take the Chinese
to the dispute settlement body of the WTO on the grounds that it is manipulating
the exchange rate to win unfair gains from trade. There effort is ostensibly
aimed at invoking a provision in the World Trade Organisation that bars
countries from influencing exchange rates to "frustrate the intent"
of WTO trade agreements. In practice, the clamour is all intended to get
the US government, in a pre-election year, to increasing pressure on China
to float its currency.
However, not all of American business supports this effort. Calman Cohen
of the Emergency Committee for American Trade, which represents many large
US companies doing business in China, is reported to have said that while
the renminbi may well be undervalued, it was not the main cause of the
industrial problems facing the US. His principal and well-founded fear
is that action against China would adversely affect US companies that
as part of their competitive strategy are sourcing their products from
countries like China.
Not surprisingly, Rob Westerhof, chief executive of Philips Electronics
North America and former chief executive of Philips Electronics East Asia,
argues: “A free float or sudden revaluation would be bad for China and
bad for business. Instead, Beijing should maintain the peg for now and
aim for a gradual revaluation of about 15 per cent over the next five
years. Free- floating the renminbi can be considered only when China has
a well established financial system. That will take at least another 10
years.” He made it clear that “business prefers a stable renminbi-dollar
exchange rate. A sudden revaluation of the renminbi would disrupt results
for the many multinational companies (Philips included) that supply American
and European retail chains with goods made in China. Currently, hedging
against exchange rate fluctuations of a free-floating, unpredictable renminbi
would be very costly for those companies.”
Unfortunately, some Asian countries, particularly those that have been
experiencing an appreciation of their currencies from the lows they reached
after the 1997 financial crisis are supporting the demand with the hope
that they would benefit from the loss of Chinese export competitiveness
that a revaluation of the renminbi would involve. Interestingly, Japan
too is part of this group, even though it is itself intervening in currency
markets to prevent the yen from appreciating too much against the dollar.
Thus at the end of September, the dollar recovered sharply against the
yen as a result of Bank of Japan intervention, conducted through the New
York Federal Reserve. This help reverse a prior downward lurch of the
dollar vis-à-vis the yen. According to information released recently
by the Japanese Finance Ministry, the government and central bank have
spent a total of $ 40 billion between August 28 and September 26, taking
the total amount spent on supporting the yen in the first nine months
of 2003 to well above $100 billion. This willingness to intervene openly
is partly explained by the fact that the G-7 has accepted that any excessive
appreciation of the yen could abort a recovery which has come after a
long while and which is seen as crucial for overall global growth. This
support for action against yen appreciation goes against the G-7’s own
recent statement that cam out in favour of exchange rate flexibility in
the world, which it is now clear was aimed at developing Asia in general
and China in particular.
Despite its own actions, the Japanese government has been willing to go
along with the demand that the Chinese and other developing Asian countries
should revalue their currency by opting for a float. Once again the fact
that the developed countries believe that developing countries should
do as the G-7 says and not as it does has been brought home.
The flaws in these arguments are obvious. A revaluation of the renminbi
may reduce China’s trade surplus with the US, but it is unlikely to trigger
either export or output growth in the US. Rather, the space vacated by
the Chinese in US markets would be occupied by some other trading country
such as Vietnam, Korea or the Philippines. Further, those Asian countries
that expect to gain from the renminbi’s revaluation would soon find that
their current account surpluses and reserves are seen as grounds for identifying
their currencies as undervalued and provide the basis for a revaluation
demand. India, with less than $90 billion of foreign exchange reserves
is already being targeted. Whatever gains would occur from China’s revaluation
would be shortlived.
Further, if China and other countries, like India, with rising reserves
are deprived of those reserves on these grounds, the capital required
to finance the current account and budget deficits accompanying US growth
would soon dry up. This would drive up interest rates in the US, cut consumption
and investment spending, make the current account deficit unsustainable,
and ensure the collapse of US growth and the dollar that the revaluation
is expected to stall.
In sum, the whole episode indicates that the desperation to protect the
current imperial order is yielding a number of scatter-brained proposals.
Economics has been reduced to deformed ideology, devoid of consistency
and rationality. Fortunately, the Chinese have thus far stood their ground
and refused to yield. Hopefully, other developing countries would also
see where their best interests lie.
October 9, 2003.
|