China's
rate of economic growth during the last quarter of
a century has left many countries craving for a similar
experience for their economies, and these countries
have been trying to replicate the Chinese 'success'
story. While there is much debate about the actual
rate of growth China has witnessed ever since it went
in for state-controlled and selective opening up of
certain sectors of its economy, economists are unanimous
in their opinion that the growth has not been insignificant
in the sectors and regions that were opened to foreign
participation. However, what is worrisome is the fact
that this growth has been an extremely skewed one.
There is growing imbalance between sectors, and both
between and within regions. According to a study by
Dali L. Yang and Houkai Wei[1],
the average annual growth rates of GNP and industrial
gross output value (GOV) in the inland regions of
China have been always lower than those achieved in
coastal China. Further, the study states that the
difference between these growth rates have gradually
increased since 1980. Gaps are also arising between
the urban and rural populations in China.
Table
1
Per Capita National Income Gap between
Coastal and Inland Regions |
Year |
Per Capita National Income
(Yuan) |
Regional Gap (c)
(%) |
|
Coastal (a) |
Inland (b) |
c
= 100*(a-b)/a |
1952 |
118 |
85 |
28.0 |
1957 |
169 |
126 |
25.4 |
1965 |
213 |
165 |
22.5 |
1970 |
258 |
187 |
27.5 |
1975 |
325 |
211 |
35.1 |
1978 |
404 |
251 |
37.9 |
1980 |
497 |
310 |
37.6 |
1985 |
897 |
552 |
38.5 |
1988 |
1429 |
850 |
40.5 |
1990 |
1650 |
1016 |
38.4 |
1991 |
1858 |
1079 |
41.6 |
1992 |
2322 |
1268 |
45.4 |
Source:
China Statistical Yearbook, various issues |
|
1992 can be considered
as the year in which China decided to speed up its
process of economic reforms. Since then the regional
gap has increased further. In 1998, the per capita
GDP of Shanghai, the richest provincial unit, was
twelve times that of Guizhou, the poorest province.
In the year 2000 the gap between incomes in coastal
and inland regions went up to 57.3 per cent.
Similarly, urban incomes are growing faster than rural
incomes. The per capita disposable income of the urban
Chinese rose from 5425 Yuan in 1998 to 7703 Yuan in
2002, a rise of almost 42 per cent in five years.
Over the same period, rural disposable income per
capita rose a meagre 14.5 per cent, from 2162 Yuan
to 2476 Yuan. However, both these increases were in
nominal terms. If one considers price increases in
real terms over this period, per capita urban disposable
income rose 13.4 per cent between 1998 and 2002, while
rural per capita disposable income rose a mere 4.8
per cent[2]. A survey
conducted by the Institute of Economics of the Chinese
Academy of Social Sciences, using data from 1988 and
1995, reveals that rural individuals make up most
of those in the lower decile income groups, while
in the higher decile groups, urban residents predominate.
An important factor behind the faster growth of urban
incomes in China in the post-reform period is income
from property, which was made possible through commercialization
and privatization of the erstwhile public housing
system. While the property income of the urban Chinese
accounted for a mere 0.49 per cent of total individual
income in 1988, by 1995 the share had gone up to 1.3
per cent.
Table 2
The Distribution of Urban and rural Individuals
Across Decile Income Groups, 1988 and
1995 (percentage) |
|
1988 |
1988 |
1995 |
1995 |
Decile Group |
Rural |
Urban |
Rural |
Urban |
Lowest |
99.24 |
0.76 |
99.36 |
0.64 |
Second |
97.94 |
2.06 |
97.41 |
1.59 |
Third |
95.37 |
4.63 |
94.95 |
5.05 |
Fourth |
89.30 |
10.70 |
90.36 |
9.64 |
Fifth |
77.53 |
22.47 |
76.95 |
23.05 |
Sixth |
56.71 |
43.29 |
55.53 |
44.47 |
Seventh |
36.37 |
63.63 |
34.16 |
65.84 |
Eighth |
24.87 |
75.13 |
23.10 |
76.90 |
Ninth |
20.47 |
79.53 |
18.92 |
81.08 |
Highest |
19.55 |
80.54 |
23.78 |
76.22 |
Note: 83179 individuals
were covered in the sampling survey of
1988 and 56435 individuals were covered
in the survey of 1995.
Source: Renwei, Zhao (2001): 'Increasing
Income Inequality in China's Transition'
in "China's Retreat from Equality: Income
distribution and Economic Transition"
edited by Carl Riskin, Zhao Renwei, and
Li Shi, M.E. Sharpe, Inc.; New York |
|
The gap between rural
and urban incomes narrowed from 1978 all through the
1980s owing to the start of the rural reform period
which saw the introduction of the household responsibility
system and the simultaneous withering of the commune
system. However, as we will observe later, the dismantling
of communes increased inequality within rural China,
even the urban–rural divide started rising again
in the 1990s. This is evident from the Lorenz curve
given below:
|
Source: Can Wang (2003):
China's GDP: Examining Provincial Disparity;
Interim Report,
International
Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Austria |
Figure 2 gives the
ratio of per capita GDP of provinces with the highest
GDP to provinces having the lowest GDP per capita[3],and
also the ratio of per capita GDP of coastal provinces
to that of inland provinces. Both ratios witness more
or less steady increases over the period under study,
with the latter exhibiting a more secular rise. The
ratio of per capita GDP of high-income and low-income
provinces also exhibits a rising trend, but the ratio
had fallen in intermittent years, particularly during
the first half of the 1960s and between 1975 and 1990.
The differentials of per capita income in rural and
urban areas between 1978 and 1995 show an almost similar
trend, but according to figures available in an article
by Zhao Renwei[4],the
urban–rural divide started rising again from
the middle of the 1980s.
|
Source: Can Wang (2003):
China's GDP: Examining Provincial Disparity;
Interim Report,
International
Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Austria |
The main reason behind
the increasing disparities between coastal and inland
China, as well as between rural and urban China, is
the coastal development policy pursued by the Chinese
government. This has led to capital, both foreign
and domestic, being invested mostly in the coastal
regions of China, with the inland areas being starved
of funds. As Figures 3-6[5]
below reveal, almost all the investment that has come
to China, particularly since the country went in for
state-controlled liberalization, has gone to the eastern
region. In 2001, 50 per cent of all FDI went to just
three locations—Guangdong province, next to
Hong Kong, the city of Shanghai, and its neighbour,
Jiangsu province. Most of the rest of the money went
to other locations up and down the coast. Inland,
and indeed in some places along the coast, the flow
was just a trickle. In 2001, Guizhou, China's poorest
province and home to nearly 40 million people, attracted
less than $30million[6].
As a consequence,
even the growth of peripheral and satellite industries
and services that usually develop in the neighbouring
areas of any industrial town or city, have been limited
to the rural areas in the coastal region of the country.
This is brought out by Table 3, which gives region-wise
data for the value of exports achieved by rural enterprises
in China. Within a span of eight years, the share
of the eastern region went up from 82.8 per cent to
92.6 per cent, while that of the central and western
regions fell from 14.6 per cent to 6.5 per cent and
2.6 per cent to a meagre 0.9 per cent, respectively.
Table 3
Total Value of Export accomplished by
Rural Enterprises in China (Amount in
billion Yuan; Shares in percentage) |
|
|
National |
East |
Central |
West |
Central+West |
1985 |
Amount |
3.90 |
3.23 |
0.57 |
0.10 |
0.67 |
Share |
100.0 |
82.8 |
14.6 |
2.6 |
17.1 |
1990 |
Amount |
48.56 |
43.09 |
4.77 |
0.70 |
5.47 |
Share |
100.0 |
88.7 |
9.8 |
1.5 |
11.3 |
1991 |
Amount |
66.99 |
59.78 |
6.26 |
0.96 |
7.22 |
Share |
100.0 |
89.2 |
9.4 |
1.4 |
10.8 |
1993 |
Amount |
235.05 |
217.56 |
15.43 |
2.05 |
17.48 |
Share |
100.0 |
92.6 |
6.5 |
0.9 |
7.4 |
Source:
Dali L. Yang and Houkai Wei (1995): Rural
Enterprise Development and Regional Policy
in China; Paper delivered at the Annual
Meeting of the Association for Asian Studies,
April 6-9, 1995; Washington D.C. |
|
The majority of those
among the Chinese people who belong to the minorities
and the rural poor reside in the inland regions. An
excessively wide regional gap could not only undermine
social stability but also disrupt political stability
and spur secessionist activities. In a bid to address
the issue of growing inequalities in the country,
the Chinese government seems to have taken steps to
bridge the spiralling gap between the coastal and
inland regions of China, as well as that between urban
and rural areas. The government's assessment
was that the widening gap was a result of the decline
in the performance of rural enterprises in coastal
and inland China, and at the 5th Conference of the
7th National People's Congress held in March
1992, it decided to 'support vigorously'
the development of rural enterprises in the central
and western regions of China. In that year the People's
Bank of China offered an additional 2 billion Yuan
worth of bank loan ration and 3 billion Yuan worth
of rural credit cooperative loan ration on the basis
of original credit planning, with a view to supporting
rural enterprises in central and western China. This
additional amount was to be provided annually for
a period of eight years, from 1993 to 2000. Another
annual special loan worth 5 billion Yuan for the years
1994–2000 was pledged by the State Council in
September 1993, to support rural enterprises in these
regions. The Agricultural Bank of China also set up
a 100 million Yuan special discount loan facility
from the last quarter of 1992 to cater to rural enterprises
in minority-nationality regions in the country. These
regions included Guangxi, Ningxia, Xinjiang and Inner
Mongolia Autonomous Region, and the provinces of Yunnan,
Guizhou and Qinghai. Besides, the Chinese government
also announced certain tax exemptions (which included
a three-year exemption from income tax for all newly
established rural enterprises in certain areas) for
rural enterprises in central and western China.
That the efforts of the Chinese government to boost
investment in the backward regions has yielded results
can be observed from Figures 3 and 4, which reveal
that the coast to inland ratios of investment in capital
construction and total investment in fixed assets
have come down in recent years. Also, local governments
of the coastal region have, of late, been encouraging
and laying stress on supporting rural enterprises
of underdeveloped regions, as rural enterprises in
the coastal region are suffering from diseconomies
caused by overconcentration and the existence of an
inter-regional dual structure. The development of
rural enterprises in inland China is further expected
to curb the constant migration, both legal and illegal,
of labourers from these regions to coastal China in
search of a livelihood, thereby easing the pressure
on the infrastructure of the coastal region.
However, despite the proclaimed efforts of the Chinese
government to spur economic activities, growth and
development in inland China, things did not turn out
as expected for the central and western regions. Rather
than helping the inland regions, the government's
policies seem to have helped the developed coastal
regions through the supply of cheap labour and raw
material from inland China. The policy initiated by
the Ministry of Agriculture's Department of
Rural Enterprises in China, avowedly to promote mutual
economic benefit and common prosperity, in essence
has meant that while coastal China will witness the
development of high and new technology-based industries
and the growth of an export-led economy, the emphasis
in inland China will rest on a strategy of resource
exploitation. Faced with a rapid rise in wages in
coastal China (the wages in eastern China being about
1.5 times higher than in inland regions), the developed
coastal areas of China will constantly try to transfer
only low-grade labour-intensive production processes
to central and western China while trying to replace
labour with capital in the medium to long run.
Heavy exploitation of the mineral resources of inland
China alongside a booming raw and processed material
industry will soon lead to environmental degradation
and resource depletion of the region, resulting in
long-term calamity. Further, as one must be aware,
the terms of trade have historically moved against
primary commodities, and there is no reason to believe
that for exports of inland China, the trend would
be defied.
Projects like the Three Gorges Dam and river interlinking,
despite being criticized for disrupting the ecological
balance, flooding some of the most fertile lands in
the country and causing environmental degradation,
are expected to reduce inequalities. In the initial
stages such projects are expected to create employment
in huge numbers, thereby increasing the income and
purchasing power of the people in the provinces in
which they are implemented. However, it is in these
same regions that such projects displace large sections
of the population. Not only do many of them fail to
be adequately resettled, even those who are resettled
find it difficult to earn a livelihood. Being resettled
in a place where the skills of the migrants might
not even be in demand, these people, particularly
the older ones among them, may find themselves without
any purchasing capacity.
Resettlement policies in China have so far benefited
the rich among those displaced more than they have
helped the poor. With rural property costing less
than urban homes, migrants who have been displaced
from rural areas get much less compensation in comparison
to those displaced from urban homes. As a result,
rural migrants are often forced to borrow money from
relatives and friends to build new houses—and
so start their new lives with a mountain of debt.
Rural migrants are also more likely to be forced to
move farther away than urban migrants, as well as
face daunting economic and social challenges in adapting
to an unfamiliar environment[7].
While the experts who were a part of the official
feasibility study team for the Three Gorges Dam have
claimed that those who were displaced because of this
project will all be resettled in the reservoir area,
and that 40 per cent of the rural migrants could be
redeployed in non-farming jobs, researchers from the
Chinese Academy of Sciences have said that the lives
of these migrants will not necessarily be better or
even the same even if the 'local resettlement'
target is met. The researchers tracked a small number
of rural migrants in the Wuqiao district of Wanxian
city, and found that most of them were significantly
less well off than they had previously been. Both
newcomers and existing residents had only half as
much land as they did before resettlement. The amount
of farmland available per person also had declined
dramatically after the influx of migrants, and the
resettlement site failed to provide new work for individuals
squeezed off the land. Almost all the households monitored
in the study had suffered increased unemployment and
a sharp decline in income. Since most of the land
available for relocation under the Three Gorges project
was barren and unsuitable for cultivation, many of
those displaced were reluctant to move to such inhospitable
conditions.
Even though the official experts had pledged that
everybody displaced by the Three Gorges project would
be rehabilitated within the reservoir area, the actual
has relocation belied their promises. Soil erosion
has become a serious problem in the Three Gorges area
with the expansion of farmland and construction of
hundreds of new settlements. To relieve the pressure
on a fragile ecosystem, in 1999, Premier Zhu Rongji
announced a policy shift in favour of moving migrants
to distant parts of the country. This decision to
move 125,000 migrants far from their homes was not
part of the original resettlement plan. Many of the
migrants found it difficult to cope in their new,
unfamiliar physical and social environments, and with
conflicts with 'host communities'. Migrants
to distant areas found that they could not speak the
local dialects and faced tremendous problems in communicating.
In March 2002, thousands of rural migrants who had
been moved under Zhu Rongji's policy to Badong
county in Hubei province, complained about substandard
resettlement conditions and asked to be relocated.
To maintain social stability, they were moved again.
However, such additional relocation has only led to
a further rise in the costs of the project.
Most of the soft loans that the Chinese government
and banks had pledged for rural enterprises in inland
China in the early 1990s have not been forthcoming.
With the banking system in China also undergoing reforms,
more emphasis is being placed on the profitability
of the projects and not on issues like employment
generation and reduction of inequality. The People's
Bank of China had initially pledged an annual loan
of 5 billion Yuan at low rates of interest to support
rural enterprises in central and western China, but
later the bank decided that it would provide the loan
purely on a commercial basis. Even then a major part
of the promised funds were not made available, and
loans provided by the agricultural banks for rural
enterprises in inland China were on the decline. Agricultural
banks and credit cooperatives still account for almost
three-fourths of the rural enterprise loans in the
eastern region of China.
Finally, even the tax benefits initially on offer
for those setting up new enterprises in rural areas
in the central and western regions of the country
were mostly withdrawn under the new tax policies that
are being implemented in China. About four-fifths
of the taxes paid by rural enterprises go to the central
government, and as such, local governments cannot
support the development of rural enterprises in those
regions through preferential tax policies. Although
the new tax regime has exempted all items of export
from value-added tax and consumer tax, the western
and the central regions hardly benefit from such largesse
as less than 10 per cent of the exports of rural enterprises
come from enterprises located in these regions.
The Chinese government has recently woken up to the
necessity of addressing the concerns of the nation's
backward provinces. The Tenth Five-Year Plan (2001–2005)
in China has the narrowing of regional inequalities
as one of its principal objectives. It pushes for
sustainable development—with increased productivity
in agriculture and in industrial state-owned enterprises
(SOEs). The Plan also intends to create jobs by promoting
labour-intensive activities, including services, and
developing collective, private and individual businesses.
The Plan hopes to create 40 million new urban jobs,
and to safeguard the natural resource base. Rural
reforms, as outlined in the Plan, aim at accelerating
agricultural diversification and raising incomes.
The new National Poverty Reduction Plan for 2001-2010
adopts a more comprehensive approach with better targeting
of the deprived population in the backward provinces
of western China. The Tenth Plan also calls for 'coordinating
economic and social development'—by paying
greater attention to quality-of-life issues, including
investing in human capital (e.g., anti-poverty measures,
better education), protecting natural capital (e.g.,
by enhanced ecological conservation and environmental
protection), and improving social protection (e.g.,
by strengthening the social security system). In particular,
China's Tenth Plan outlines the need for developing
the country's economically and socially lagging
western and central provinces—by fostering economic
development zones through investments in strategic
physical infrastructure for transport, water resources
management, energy and mining, accelerating other
development objectives as cited above, and introducing
advanced technologies to upgrade local industries
and increase competitiveness.
It is essential that the competitiveness of China's
backward regions improves, not only in primary commodities
and as providers of raw materials for the country's
industrial belt, but also in manufactured and finished
products. Regional inequality in China is bound to
keep widening as long as thrust of the policy of the
Chinese government remains development of inland China
as a feeder and provider for the country's coastal
region. Investments need to be made in central and
western China not only in the resource exploitation
and processing industries, to cater to the demand
of the export-oriented eastern region, but also in
sectors from where ready-to-export-products can be
manufactured, ridding the economy of inland China
of its dependence on how China's coastal economy
performs. Also, the government has to monitor the
flow of resources into the backward regions so that
agriculture does not get neglected and sufficient
investment flows into the agricultural sector. Food
security of the people of inland China cannot be compromised
in the pursuit of industrial growth.
October 15, 2003.
[1] Dali L. Yang and Houkai Wei (1995):
Rural Enterprise Development and Regional Policy in
China; Paper delivered at the Annual Meeting of the
Association for Asian Studies, April 6-9, 1995; Washington
D.C.
[2]
http://www.friedlnet.com/images/free_chinese_statistical_communique_2002.pdf
[3] Ratio of high/low GDP per capita:
The ratio of high/low GDP per capita (hereafter denoted
as RHL) is defined as the ratio of the top per capita
GDP to the lowest per capita GDP among the provinces.
In order to avoid some special causes of disparity,
such as a too small area and/or sparse population
in a certain province, the RHL in this study is expressed
by using the ratio of the arithmetic mean value of
per capita GDP of the top five provinces to that of
the bottom five provinces.
[4] Renwei, Zhao (2001): 'Increasing
Income Inequality in China's Transition' in "China's
Retreat from Equality: Income distribution and Economic
Transition" edited by Carl Riskin, Zhao Renwei,
and Li Shi, M.E. Sharpe, Inc.; New York.
[5] Source of Figures 3-6: Houkai,
Wei: China's Regional Disparities and Regional Policies;
Institute of Industrial Economics; Chinese Academy
of Social Sciences
[6]
http://www.globalpolicy.org/socecon/ffd/2003/0119chinafdi.htm
[7]
http://www.threegorgesprobe.org/tgp/index.cfm?DSP=content&ContentID=7008
|