On
September 21, 2003, the World Bank unveiled its annual
flagship publication, the 2004 World Development Report,
entitled "Making Services Work for Poor People."
The WDR's main premise is that basic services - primary
education, basic health care, water and electricity
services -fail to reach the poor because too many
governments lack sound and representative institutions
of governance. Ironically, the report expresses strong
confidence in the ability of these same unaccountable
governments to regulate private service provision.
In addition to deficient institutions, the WDR attributes
failing public services to regressive budgets (that
benefit mostly the middle class), petty corruption,
and bureaucratic inertia. Among the many solutions
it proposes for these problems are more progressive
resource allocation, greater transparency, more competition,
and citizen-based monitoring. It also encourages policy-makers
to consider decentralizing service provision and -particularly
in the areas of water and electricity – implementing
private provision and higher user fees.
While the WDR is enthusiastic about the potential
of markets to improve some essential services –
often too enthusiastic, as discussed in this critique
-it also makes clear that there are limits to private
provision. Since the Bank's critics accuse the institution
of promoting indiscriminate privatization, the World
Bank has been using the WDR in public and press relations
as evidence to counter such attacks.
The WDR's qualified support for public provision is
an important statement to have on record in the public
debate over reform of basic social services, like
primary education and health care. The importance
of the state's role in service provision is even more
emphatic in the 2003 Human Development Report (HDR),
entitled "Millennium Development Goals: A compact
among nations to end human poverty." The UN Development
Programme report urges a larger role for government
in the direct provision of social services, and concludes
that: "The supposed benefits of privatizing social
services are elusive, with inconclusive evidence on
efficiency and quality standards in the private relative
to the public sector. Meanwhile, examples of market
failures in private provisioning abound." (p.
113)
Notwithstanding its support for public provision of
education and basic health care, the WDR endorses
private provision of infrastructure services, such
as water, sanitation, and energy. The report seeks
to justify the World Bank's past and present efforts
to privatize utilities by neglecting the mounting
evidence of unacceptable risks of private provision
in these sectors – especially in countries with
weak regulatory capacity.
While the WDR carefully avoids a "silver bullet"
for improving basic services, many of the reforms
that it proposes are informed by an important underlying
principle; that government should not both regulate
and provide service provision. Indeed, the WDR suggests
that public services tend to fail poor people because
the fusion of these functions represents a conflict
of interest. "When the policymaker takes a separate
role from the provider, it is easier to say "I
don't care what your problem is, just tell me the
vaccination rates. Or the test scores. Or crime rates."
When roles are mixed, bureaucracies become insular
and tend to hide mistakes." (p. 98) The WDR does
concede that most basic services in developed countries
are delivered by government providers which are overseen
by government regulators – and that this arrangement
works just fine. But it rejects the same path for
today's developing countries. Why?
Rich countries benefit from a long evolution of the
relationships between the state and frontline providers.
Almost all services provided directly to individuals
in the now -rich countries were originally provided
privately. They were eventually absorbed or consolidated
by a state institution that had been separate from
the existing provider organizations. The state began
as an independent outside monitor and regulator of
private activities. It largely retained that independence
as a monitor after the same activities became public.
For the developing world the desire for rapid expansion
of public financing and provision short-circuits this
historical development. Both the monitoring and the
provision are taking place simultaneously. This is
not necessarily a bad thing-the poor might otherwise
have to wait much longer for services to reach them.
But it does show that the current institutional features
of rich countries may not transfer directly to poor
countries without the establishment of a complementary
regulatory structure, a structure that may need to
be established beforehand. (p.99)
This explanation represents much more than a novel
theory of development for academics to debate about.
The imperative to separate policymakers (i.e., regulators)
from service providers justifies the replacement of
government service provision.
The present critique rejects the WDR's argument for
two reasons: First, the report does not account for
variation in outcome. As the WDR shows in numerous
places, the developing world is filled with examples
of effective and accountable government services which
are regulated by the same government. Why wasn't good
governance "short-circuited" by late and
rapid development in these cases? Second, and most
fundamentally, because basic public services are susceptible
to market failures, there is widespread agreement
that government must be able to regulate private providers.
Yet if poor countries don't have "institutional
features of rich countries" needed make government
services work, they can hardly be expected to establish
complex regulatory structures needed for private service
provision.
This paper is organized into three sections: The first
focuses on the WDR's analytical framework, the second
on its policy implications, and the last on the relationship
between the report's main messages and actual World
Bank operations. The author thanks Nancy Alexander
for her review and many substantive contributions
to this critique.
A. Analytical framework
Anecdotes, not analysis
If one looks to the WDR to provide analytical guidance
about how to choose among options for reform –
especially between government and private provision
-the report is not particularly useful. That is, it
fails to provide policy-makers with the kinds of tools
needed to evaluate the costs, risks and trade-offs
inherent of different policy options in the context
of particular institutional and economic constraints.
Especially with respect to the social sectors, the
message of the WDR seems to be "let a thousand
flowers bloom." The WDR is filled with seemingly
random claims that private, public or decentralized
provision has worked well somewhere in the past. There
is an example somewhere in the document to support
the viability of just about any kind of known reform.
For example, under a properly pro-poor government:
"an easy to monitor services such as immunization
could be delivered by the public sector, or financed
by the public sector and contracted out to the private
or non-profit sector."
One could excuse a policy-maker for asking: aside
from government, firms and NGOs, who else could deliver
this service? And more importantly, how does a government
decide which one to go with? At the end of the section
on how to scale up service reform, the WDR Overview
concludes: "In addition to creating and disseminating
information, other reforms to improve service delivery
will require careful consideration of the particular
setting . . . Everything from publicly financed central
government provision to user-financed community provision
can work (or fail to work) in different circumstances."
Unfortunately, the WDR's main analytical framework
does not focus on country-specific circumstances,
but rather generic qualities of services themselves.
(An exception would be whether the political environment
is "pro-poor" or not – a slippery
and undefined concept that can be endlessly manipulated
according to one's preferred policy outcome.)
Shaky analytical framework
The WDR attempts to provide an analytical framework
-a highly technocratic approach to selecting service
reforms. The recommendations are based on three sets
of criteria:
1. Are client preferences homogeneous or heterogeneous?
2. Are politics "pro-poor" or "pro-rich?"
3. Are outputs easy or hard to monitor?
Some rather odd policy recommendations emerge from
the WDR's framework.[1]
For example, there is only one set of circumstances
in which central government provision is recommended:
pro-poor politics, homogeneous clients and difficulty
in monitoring outcomes. It stretches credulity that,
out the eight possible combinations of criteria, the
public service option that has been used most often
and most effectively in the wealthy northern countries
appears to have extremely limited applicability in
developing countries.
The three dualistic, "black and white" criteria
are unhelpful since the real world is colored in countless
shades of gray. For example, few political scientists
would have the temerity to assign a categorical pro-rich
or pro-poor classification across service sectors
to countries they have studied closely. Moreover,
because of political, ethnic or religious considerations
– and of course pervasive gender bias –
politics may prove to be quite "pro-poor"
for certain groups or areas but not for others. An
event so fleeting as a change in government can significantly
can significantly improve or worsen the political
status of poor people. Given that the WDR's policy-recommendations
differ significantly depending on whether a country
is deemed to have pro-poor politics, the many difficult
ies in measuring the criterion present serious challenges
for policy-makers.
In the case of heterogeneity, even if there is little
deba te over the clarity of the criterion, its role
in the analytical framework is overly simplistic.
When consumer preference is found to be "heterogeneous"—that
is, when different users have different tastes or
needs – the WDR supports some variant of local
government or even community control. However, decentralization
is a national policy, affecting all local governments
– even those that are manifestly corrupt and
deaf to the needs of the poor. Giving more responsibility
to weak or unaccountable government is unlikely to
provide more choices for heterogeneous clients. Contrary
to WDR claims that decentralization improves the welfare
of the poor outcomes, empirical research suggests
that "the notion that there is a predictable
or general link between decentralization of government
and the development of more pro-poor policies or poverty
alleviation outcomes clearly lacks any convincing
evidence." [2]
Sustainability of Community-Driven
Development
The WDR is enthusiastic about decentralized, community-driven
development (CDD) projects and acknowledge the importance
of strengthening local government to administer them.
However, the Bank's CDD resources typically bypass
local government and, by the Bank's own estimation,
have very low sustainability rates. For instance,
a significant sample of CDD (Social Fund) water operations
revealed a likely sustainability of 24 percent of
operations. In addition, the poverty reduction impact
of World Bank financing of community-driven development
initiatives is weak. The Bank's own evaluation department
concluded that Social Funds, one of the main financing
mechanisms for community development projects, did
not improve most welfare indicators relative to a
control group. In fact, it found that non-poor communities
were more likely to benefit from Social Fund expenditures
than the poor.* For a
critical review of the rise of social funds in development
aid, Judith Tendler," why Are Social Funds So
Popular?" in Local Dynamics in the Era of Globalization
(Shahid Yusuf, ed.) Oxford University Press, 2000.
*OED, Social Funds: Assessing
Effectiveness, World Bank, 2002
And what about communities? The WDR itself concedes
that "communities are not homogeneous –
problems of exclusion and elite capture can be the
same as in government systems." One would hope
that such a caveat would come with guidance on how
to assess the readiness of communities to make investment
decisions and allocate resources accountably. Yet
notwithstanding extensive evidence of corruption,
patronage and social exclusion within local governments
and communities, the WDR touts highly risky policies
as bringing services closer to the people.
Moreover, even where decentralized government is accountable,
all too often it is also broke. The trend toward decentralization
has created "unfunded mandates" in country
after country, especially as fiscal transfers from
the central government are reduced – often under
direction from the same multilateral lenders who thought
decentralization was the solution for better services.
The WDR framework asks only if the service is appropriate
for local government, and fails to examine whether
the local government has sustainable financing and
capacity to deliver services.
The criterion monitoring is also much more slippery
than the authors admit. For example, the WDR casually
claims that water and electricity are "easily
monitored services." (p. 14) It is true that
checking the existence of a household connection to
a utility network is easier to verify than knowing
whether a child is being properly taught. However,
this does not mean that monitoring water and electricity
services is "easy," particularly for governments
that lack regulatory capacity.
Avoiding market failure in private infrastructure
provision requires accurate monitoring of both performance
and costs. World Bank economist Vivien Foster has
argued that a "regulated company will have a
strong incentive to abuse this strategic advantage
[its control over information] by under-supplying
information or distorting the information supplied."
[3] Private sector providers
have incentives to maximize profits and provide minimal
compliance for contractual commitments that serve
social rather than revenue-generating goals. In order
to monitor their behavior, regulators must gather
extensive data at considerable cost.
Generic advice
Policy-makers would do well to focus on specific,
observed constraints to implementing private provision.
Changing the analytical framework to focus on actual
context instead of generic attributes could help focus
national and local deliberations about policy options.
Instead of using mechanical and largely abstract notions
of service types, policy-makers should focus instead
on the known problem . The WDR itself identifies four
distinct ways that services fail poor people:
1. Too much spending on the non-poor;
2. Failure of expenditures to reach front-line providers;
3. Corruption and disincentives among service workers
themselves; and
4. Lack of demand among the poor, due to economic,
informational or cultural factors.
As discussed below, this critique proposes adding
a fifth problem: inadequate budget.
The main questions driving the WDR's analytical framework
are: "What kind of service do I have, and what
kind of reform is best for that kind of service?"
But a quick glance around the world shows the folly
of this approach. Countries successfully employ every
imaginable variation of service provision: decentralization;
and community control; monitoring systems (ranging
from citizen participation to high tech computerization);
and private provision (through corporations, small
businesses and NGOs). (And of course, there have been
failures with each of these approaches as well.) Successes
are obviously not inextricably tied to the nature
of the service. Rather, they were achieved because
of the actual country context – that is, the
constraints and opportunities specific to the country
or locality.
An alternative question that would drive the analysis
in reforming a failing service is: "What is the
root of the existing problem?" Unlike general
attributes, the answer to this question is not "given."
The service must be investigated, the perspectives
of managers, workers and users understood. Stakeholders
would also provide information about assets and capabilities
that are worth building on. By identifying the institutions
that provide technical competence, accountability,
and pro-poor advocacy, services could be reformed
based on an understanding of context-specific opportunities.
By using this kind of analytical framework, there
is little doubt that many of the reforms proposed
in the WDR
– including those involving private participation
– would emerge as appropriate solutions. But
these solutions would result from on-the-ground consultation.
B. Policy implications
for private provision and resource allocation
Bad advice on privatization
of infrastructure
The WDR is enthusiastic about direct private provision
of infrastructure services. Because the WDR's analytical
framework does not include an assessment of the well-known
risks associated with asymmetric information,[4]
it offers extremely questionable advice on infrastructure
services. The report maintains that government's role
in these sectors should generally be limited to regulation
and subsidies. The reason is that: "There are
few advantages to the government's providing the [infrastructure]
service itself, which explains why the past decade
has seen many privatizations, concessions and the
like in water and energy."[5]
Are water and Electricity Public
Goods?
The WDR's distinct policy advice for social and infrastructure
services reveals that its authors do not regard water
and electricity as "Public goods." For example,
Box 2 (Overview), entitled, "Service-a public
responsibility "refers only to health and education.
Why? First these services are replete with market
failures-with externalities, as when an infected child
spreads a disease to playmates, or a farmer benefits
from a neighbor's ability to read. So the private
sector, left to its devices, will not achieve the
level of health and education that society desires.
Second basic health and education are considered fundamental
human rights," Later, the report justifies charging
user fees "for water, electricity and other services
whose benefits are enjoyed mainly by the user…"
(p. 10) (Strangely, in the same paragraph the WDR
recognizes water quality as a public good, because
of public health externalities. Why water quality
would be considered as a public good but water access
would not remains unclear, given that access has an
obvious impact on public health. Indeed, it is lack
of access to safe drinking water that leads poor people
to contaminated water resources.)
These points are certainly valid, but they apply with
equal force to water and electricity. Water and sanitation
services obviously provide tremendous positive externalities,
preventing the spread of waterborne diseases (such
as cholera, which killed hundreds of South Africans
following the imposition of user fees.) Electricity
also provides important benefits that extend well
beyond the consumer, including higher economic productivity
and growth, and promoting public education bye enabling
children to study at night. As for what can happen
to electricity service when the private sector is
"left to its devices," one need recall the
traumatic price hikes and blackouts that plagued California
and the US northeast. Finally, the UN has explicitly
identified access to safe drinking water as fundamental
human rights, once again making the distinction between
water and health care seem arbitrary.
Given the disastrous record of privatized water and
energy, one would expect some elaboration on the sweeping
dismissal of public provision. The WDR does not mention
what the "few advantages" of public service
might be, or how those advantages can be compared
to those of private provision. As this critical assessment
is left to the reader's imagination, a few advantages
of direct public provision are offered here:
No need to regulate firms with incentives and capacity
to withhold information needed for pricing and investment
decisions. While government provision does require
regulation, achieving accountable supervision of a
public utility is qualitatively different –
and much less costly – than for a private one.
No monopolistic rent-seeking or market manipulation.
Under government provision of a natural monopolies
or erratic markets like energy generation, there is
no incentive to charge monopolistic prices or distort
supply. Similarly, government provision requires no
profit margin, which increases prices for consumers.
No corrupt bidding process or sweetheart deals on
private concessions.
When service is poor, service users can exercise demands
more effectively as organized citizens, rather than
atomized customers.
World Bank research has recognized the importance
of regulation when it comes to private provision of
monopoly services, especially network-based sectors
that are not subject to competition. The WDR itself
includes a section on the importance of competent
and autonomous regulation in ensuring that providers
– public or private – be held accountable.
Yet even though most of the Bank's borrowing governments
have relatively weak regulatory capacity – especially
in terms of monitoring and sanctioning powerful private
sector firms, the WDR embraces privatization of water
and energy.[6]
Privatization Paradox
WDR's facile advice in favor of infrastructure privatization
underscores a fundamental dilemma of development that
the World Bank fails to confront: The same accountability
limitations that make public services fail will almost
certainly undermine the effectiveness of private provision
and decentralized services. The simple reason is that,
no matter who provides a service, the state is ultimately
responsible for regulating the provider and protecting
consumers. The report observers that: "Providers
end up being more accountable to policymakers than
to clients, which breaks the long route of accountability"
which depends on the collective political power of
the citizenry. Importantly, this is not a problem,
by definition, when serving the public interest is
the policy-maker's priority.
The WDR argues that there can be a conflict of interest
when government policy-makers regulate government
providers. It strongly underscores how private provision
is a solution because it separates these functions.
However, the report does not ask why so many countries
succeed in putting regulators and providers "under
one roof." More seriously, it implausibly suggests
putting regulators and providers "under one roof."
More seriously, it implausibly suggests that consumers
(including the poor) will be better off when the same,
ostensibly unaccountable policy-makers regulate private
providers instead of government providers.
Avoiding Tough Question About
Equity
The WDR encourages governments to attract private
investment by liberalizing and deregulating the services
they provide. It's true that opening up essential
services may attract investor. However, the private
sector often engages in "cherry picking,"
or "cream-skimming." Firms have little incentive
to invest in "unprofitable people." In the
case of utilities, private providers like to expand
household access (e.g. hook up water pipes, make connection
to electrical grid) or upgrade services in urban area,
especially where middle class consumers demand more
and better services.
They are less likely to go into peri-uban, slum or
rural areas, where topography is more difficult, per
capita consumption is less, and most importantly,
incomes are lower. Cherry picking also constrains
investment in the health care sector. Private hospitals
prefer to serve drop those who develop conditions
requiring medical attention. As a result, liberalizing
services is increasingly associated with the establishment
of a two-tired services supply with a corporate segment
focused on the healthy and wealthy and an under-financed
public sector focusing on the poor and sick.
As noted above, the WDR's main premise is that services
fail to reach the poor because too many governments
lack sound and representative institutions of governance.
So it is a mystery why the report expresses such confidence
in the ability of these same unaccountable governments
to regulate private water and energy concessions.
The report explains that as a result of weak citizen
voice, "pub lic services often become the currency
of political patronage and clientelism."
(p. 7) But how will this same neglected citizenry
force its own corrupt government to avoid enriching
itself through shady deals with private firms with
strong rent-seeking incentives and resources? The
report even warns: "If there is no good legal
system and the civil service is subject to bribes
. . . private sector contracts might be a major source
of corruption." Yet how many of the Bank's borrowing
members - especially those among the least developed
countries
- do not have these characteristics?
The WDR's general description of proper regulatory
features for the water sector is sensible enough.
However, what would be more useful than making the
uncontroversial argument that good regulation is necessary,
is an ex-ante appraisal of regulatory capacity. Surely
even the World Bank would have to admit that there
are some places in the world in which meaningful regulation
– and therefore private provision of a monopoly
network -is simply not an option. If it were possible
to benchmark standards and measure regulatory capacity
needed for different kinds of private provision, policy-makers
would have more confidence in their decisions to privatize
or reform existing public services.
Do budgets matter?
The WDR's answer to the question seems to be: only
marginally. One of the report's central arguments
is that more money won't be enough to improve services
when budgets are regressive (e.g., benefit primarily
the non-poor) or when service providers lack incentives
to reach the poor. That's fair enough. But while the
report makes an important case for reforming the way
services are delivered, it fails to acknowledge the
damage that budget cutting -often under imposed structural
adjustment loans -has caused public services over
the last 20 years. Today the IMF still ties much of
its financing to conditions that national and local
governments cut back resources available for delivering
public services.
At World Bank seminar in May 2003, economist Jeff
Sachs chastised the international organizations, including
the World Bank, for unfairly lowering the expectations
of what is possible in the water and sanitation sector.
Indeed, he blamed the institutions for putting developing
countries on a starvation diet for twenty years and
insisted that huge amounts of public funding are required
to achieve functioning water supply systems. Sachs
said that "if public-private partnerships are
a means to get the private sector to do work that
only the public sector can pay for, it will be a sad
experiment."
Not even the most ardent defenders of government services
argue that more money is the whole solution. Service
providers can be made more responsive and efficient
through better manageme nt techniques, greater autonomy
to frontline workers, and more transparent information
about resources and performance. But surely the budget
is often a major part of the solution as well.
Ironically, the World Bank's own press release, "Key
Services Often Fail Poor People," highlights
this fact through examples: "Indonesia used its
oil windfalls to build new schools and hire more teachers,
doubling primary enrollment to 90 percent by 1986.
A program in Mexico that gives cash to poor households
if they visited a clinic regularly and their children
attended school reduced illness among children by
20 percent, and increased secondary enrollment by
5 percentage points for boys and 8 for girls."
The Indonesian case might suggest that all developing
countries should use their vast petroleum wealth to
improve social services, good advice that regrettably
may go unheeded in countries with more limited natural
resource endowments. And while the Mexican program
may be innovative, its key element appears to be "cash."
In other words, budgets do matter. The point is so
obvious that it should hardly need emphasizing, but
the WDR's skepticism over increasing budgets makes
it necessary to re-state the obvious. The WDR is right
to caution against throwing good money after bad and
insisting on the most efficient and accountable public
services possible. But it should make this point in
the context of guidance for how to assess resources
gaps and suggestions for overcoming those gaps.
The WDR's position on budgets is also problematic
because it arbitrarily separates the issue of resources
from the level of performance. Any analysis of failing
services should address the potential relation of
the overall sector budget to other shortcomings of
government providers. Reformers should start by asking
the simple question of cause and effect: Are corruption,
indifference and inefficiency the independent causes
of failing services, or are they the outcomes of a
fiscal straightjacket? When service providers perform
poorly, the WDR takes a general position that the
problems are entrenched within the organizational
culture or wider political system. In analytical terms,
it treats budgets, productivity and accountability
as conceptually separate issues. The possibility that
greater resources can, by themselves, improve productivity
and accountability, is not seriously considered.
The WDR largely ignores the possibility that starving
public services of funds can lead directly to inefficiency,
corruption and professional apathy. As the Overview
argues, "As resources become more productive,
the argument for additional resources becomes more
persuasive." Of course in many cases existing
resources are badly mismanaged. But in making this
claim, the WDR takes a categorical position that the
productivity of services is not related to the level
of resources available. Yet in the case of infrastructure,
low budgets postpone investment and maintenance, leading
to physical deterioration that inevitably undermines
productivity. In the social services, budget cuts
have led to reduced salaries, shabby working conditions
and inadequate supplies. These conditions increase
incentives for petty bribery and also demoralize professionals
who see little chance of making a difference.
Finally, one of the WDR's most important progressive
policy recommendations is lifeline rates or free minimum
services to poor people (see discussion below). Especially
where poverty is pervasive, making such subsidies
possible will obviously require tremendous increases
in service budgets.
User fee issues
The WDR makes a useful analytical contribution on
the controversial subject of user fees. In the context
of widespread criticism of Bank-financed policy reforms
that impose commercial pricing on the poor, the WDR
emphatically states that there should be "no
blanket policy on user fees." (See Box 4.4) It
also provides an interesting analytical framework
for helping policy-makers determine when user fees
are appropriate, and with what kinds of complementary
measures to protect the poor. The WDR also supports
the imposition of user fees for services not used
primarily by the poor, to ensure that the middle class
is not the primary beneficiary of public resources.
Three particular recommendations, however, merit special
scrutiny – not because they are wrong, but because
they are highly susceptible to political discretion.
Lifeline rates. When it is difficult to distinguish
the poor from the non-poor, the WDR promotes user
fees with "lifeline" rates that provide
a base level of service for free or at a highly subsidized
price. This is clearly a progressive option, and is
likely to avoid administrative difficulties associated
with targeted subsidies, especially for meter-based
services like water and electricity. South Africa
adopted a national law allowing 6 kl of water and
20-50 kwh of electricity per month free per family.
While free and lifeline rates are good ideas in principle,
they are tough to do right in practice. Simply determining
"how much" of a service satisfies basic
needs of the poor is fraught with political and economic
controversy. Indeed, many argue that South Africa's
pioneering laws do not come close to providing sufficient
water and electricity for poor families. For governments
facing budget pressures and MDB requirements to reduce
deficits (or increase primary surpluses), the path
of least resistance is to ignore such pro-poor measures
or make them so limited as to leave the poor highly
vulnerable. This brings us back to the central issue
of resources. Despite the WDR's insistence than "more
money isn't enough," poor countries will obviously
need a lot more money to make lifeline rates a reality.
Targeting. When it is
possible to distinguish the poor from the non-poor,
the WDR promotes user fees while targeting poor people
with direct money transfers or exemptions from payment.
This may be progressive in principle, but in practice
can be extremely difficult to do with precision and
equity. Studies of "targeted" subsid y and
voucher schemes show high levels of "leakage"
(benefits going to the non-poor) and exclusion (of
the poor). Particularly in countries or areas where
the vast majority of people are poor, targeted subsidies
are likely to be administratively overwhelming and
economically unfeasible.
User fees. Fundamentally,
the WDR accepts user fees as a "necessary evil"
when the service will not be "adequately delivered
without user fees." [7]
The argument is tautological: User fees must be used
when services cannot be delivered without user fees.
The underlying question, of course, is how to determine
when this situation exists. According to the WDR,
the situation "calls for an honest appraisal
of the ability [of government] to deliver services
along the long route [where citizens hold policy-makers
accountable for making sure that service providers
do their job]. If teachers or medical providers cannot
be supervised and medical stores not maintained by
government, then clients, by default, must bring purchasing
power to bear." (Box 4.4)
Similarly, the WDR argues that when politicians increase
their power by providing subsidized electricity services
mainly to wealthier constituencies: "Reducing
those rents by raising tariffs or having the private
sector provide electric ity, even if it violates the
principles of equity – they are already violated
in the existing system – may be the only way
of improving electricity services to the poor."
(p. 13)
To paraphrase the WDR's argument, user fees are acceptable
when policy-makers or public service providers are
not accountable. The problem with this position is
that it involves a tremendous judgment call that can
easily be influenced by fiscal considerations or World
Bank pressure. When is the public sector "beyond
hope?" By cla iming that user fees are justified
when policy-makers pursue political goals or don't
hold providers accountable (and are therefore unresponsive
to their own citizens) the WDR provides a potential
loophole for full cost recovery for virtually any
poorly performing service. (In the case of patronage-based
subsidies, it would seem that corrupt and self-interested
policy-makers who are pressured into privatizing a
public service would have every incentive and opportunity
to enrich themselves further at the pub lic's expense,
and little interest in ensuring that the firm serves
poor people.)
Before turning to regressive user fees, shouldn't
policy-makers attempt to make providers more responsive?
The WDR identifies plenty of ideas for how to make
this happen, including more transparent disclosure
of information and getting citizens involved in monitoring
the service. If reaching the poor is truly the goal
of the World Bank, then it stands to reason that it
would encourage borrowing governments to first attempt
to improve accountability – or ensure proper
allocation of lifeline resources to the poor -before
imposing regressive user fees. By using accountability
as a pretext for commercial pricing (incidentally,
a common step prior to privatization) the Bank essentially
"throws up its hands" and admits defeat
in the attempt to improve the lives of the poor.
Preconceptions about workers
distorts judgment [8]
Much of the report treats workers as a problem—often
the problem. It is filled with many critical references
to bad worker behavior, such as absenteeism or even
hitting patients. It sees greater discipline, and
even the insecurity of the labor market, as methods
for ‘dealing' with these problems. But for the
most vital public services, like education and healthcare,
the workers are the service – the teachers,
nurses, and others. Their income, capacity, and motivation
are key factors in the performance of public utilities.
The report fails to explore these issues properly
– and distorts the understanding of some of
its own case studies of good practice.
For example, it references Uganda's successful increase
in primary school enrolment which resulted from cutting
school fees, but fails to add that education quality
has suffered because no extra teachers have been employed,
leading to classes with over 100 students. It also
refers to improvements in primary healthcare performance
in Cambodia, which it presents as an example of what
can be achieved by contracting-out to NGOs. But its
own information clearly shows that the two key measures
were abolishing user charges, and paying higher wages
to workers, reducing their incentive to seek payments
from patients.
The report duly notes the great advances made in health
care reforms during the 1980s and 1990s in state of
Ceara, Brazil. But it fails to mention the importance
of the treatment of the workforce. The major work
on these reforms, written by MIT professor Judith
Tendler and cited in the WDR's bibliography,[9]
explains that "the workers in these programmes
showed high dedication to their jobs [and that] government
itself fed the high dedication of these workers with
repeated public demonstrations of admiration and respect
for what they were doing . . . All this contributed
to a new respect for these workers by the public –
remarkable in a time of widespread contempt for government."
Tendler pointedly contrasted these findings with "development
advice in which the public servant is presumed guilty
of self-interest unless proven otherwise" –
a description that fits the WDR all too well.
As with every topic related to public services, the
WDR avoids being completely categorical. The Overview
offers the following: "Many, often the majority
[or frontline service providers are driven by intrinsic
motivation to serve." If the WDR authors truly
believed this to be true, it's a wonder that they
dedicate so little of their report to supporting and
rewarding that intrinsic motivation, and so much to
controlling and disciplining worker behavior. Moreover,
the report skirts the issue of abrogation of workers'
rights when privatization processes violate labor
agreements.
C. World Bank operations
In terms of its operational impact on World Bank activities,
the WDR's most important words may be those that follow
the copyright information three pages before the first
word on Page One. Although the WDR is routinely identified
as a World Bank publication and suggestive of its
current thinking on development policy, one may be
surprised to discover that its "findings, interpretations,
and conclusions . . . do not necessarily reflect the
views of the Board of Executive Directors of the World
Bank or the governments they represent. The World
Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included
in this publication and accepts no responsibility
whatsoever for any consequences of their use."
As the WDR authors so rightly point out, accountability
in public institutions is hard to achieve.
When it comes to public relations and press coverage,
the World Bank Group is actively taking credit for
the progressive and sensible recommendations of the
WDR: the need for more pro-poor budgeting, lifeline
rates and free services for the poor, greater transparency,
the need for strong regulation of private service
provision, the principled rejection of user fees for
primary education, and doing away with the "project
implementation unit," which was found to fragment
government capacity. However, as the publication disclaimer
suggests, when it comes to actual lending practices,
evidence shows that the same organization often flouts
the WDR's good advice whenever and wherever it chooses.
But perhaps no area is as controversial as World Bank
conditionality, criticized by citizen groups, academics
and (usua lly former) government officials for undermining
democratic processes and imposing policies that just
don't work. In the chapter "Donors and service
reform," the WDR states that "donors attempt
to [promote citizen voice by] imposing conditions
and setting performance criteria on aid flows where
voice is weak . . ." (p. 209, emphasis added.)
The claim is remarkable in two ways: first, it turns
out that conditionality has always been about empowering
the poor, even though the poor have been the most
vociferous opponents of World Bank conditions. Second,
although conditions are attached to virtually all
adjustment loans in all borrowing countries, they
have been imposed only "where voice is weak."
To its credit, the WDR concedes that "donor conditions
are fundamentally different than citizen voice."
Although they were imposed with the best of intentions
and only with the true interests of the poor in mind,
"traditional conditionality does not work well."
But if one expects such an insight to result in a
new approach to lending, disappointment awaits. The
WDR's explanation for why traditional conditions fail
is lack of political commitment – not the appropriateness
of the reforms themselves.
"There is ample evidence today that conditions
based on promises do no t work well, because they
undermine ownership of the reform program. When policy-makers
are not encouraged to develop their own positions
on, say, privatization of water supply and other services,
but rely on donor conditions in taking action, they
can more easily deny responsibility for a later failure."
(p. 209)
The tortured logic of the statement merits closer
attention. The World Bank "encourages" policy-makers
to develop positions identical to its own –
from water privatization to trade liberalization -
through a variety of instruments, such as technical
assistance, capacity-building, and public statements
confirming the wisdom of the government's liberalization
efforts.[10] The quote
also suggests that when privatization fails –
and it has failed a lot – the reason is not
flawed policy, but rather insufficient commitment
on the part of a government pressured into doing it.
Ownership: The gap between rhetoric
and reality
The WDR observes that "Donors still underestimate
how difficult it is to influence reform without undercutting
domestic constituencies." (p. 203) That's an
understatement. In June 2003, the World Bank released
a survey by Princeton Survey Research Associates based
on interviews with 2,600 "Opinion formers"
in 48 countries that found a "Consistent and
overwhelming" view (From all regions and countries)
that the World Bank forces its agenda on developing
countries. Only 22 percent of respondents reported
that the Bank is doing a good job on reducing poverty.
(1) Not surprisingly, the WDR's chapter on donors
contains very little on how the World Bank and other
international institutions undermine country ownership
through everyday lending practices, which in addition
to policy conditionality, include: Starving the public
sector. In a study of electricity reform in six countries
(Argentina, India, Indonesia, Bulgaria, Ghana and
South Africa), the World Resources Institute found
that reforms were always driven by the immediate need
for capital, usually as a result of the withdrawal
of international donor support for the power sector.
(2) Issuance of Decrees. IMF and World Bank adjustment
programs routinely call for the Executive to issue
decrees to privatize resources and services, or recoup
costs through tariffs and user fees. In reference
to Latin America, three veteran World Bank officials
note the importance of rules and legislation that
strengthen the office of the presidency in relation
to the legislature, including "powers to rule
by decree" and "an unassailable presidential
veto."
(3) Some of these reforms appear to reverse democratic
progress in representative institutions achieved with
great struggle over the last decades. Public Relations
Campaigns. A recent communications "toolkit"
Published by the World Bank's external relations department
identifies democratization as a constraint to privatization.
(4) It never suggests that Bank or Government actually
assess the merit of arguments voiced by citizens opposed
such policies. (They are simply dismissed as propaganda
from rent-seeking groups.) Moreover, in what may be
a direct violation of its own Articles of Agreement,
which prohibits interference in domestic political
affairs of borrowers, the Bank's toolkit instructs
Bank task team leaders on how to work with national
legislatures to overturn parliamentary opposition
to privatization, ad offers guidance on how to build
legislative coalitions in favor of the policy.
(1)The Global Poll: Multinational
Survey of Opinion Leaders 2002, Princeton Survey Research
Associates (siteresources.worldbank.org/NEWS/Resources/globalpoll.pdf)
(2) Navroz Dubash, Power Politics: Equity and Environment
in Electricity Reform, WRI, 2002.
(3)Shahid Javed Burki, Guillermo Perry and William
Dillinger. Beyond the Center: Decentralizing the State.
World Bank, Washington, DC, 1999.
(4)Public Communication Programs for Privatization
Projects: A Toolkit for World Bank Task Team Leaders
and Clients, World Bank, 2003.
The resulting recommendation for how to change lending
practices is extremely significant – and disturbing.
Rather than rethink the soundness of privatization
policies in general, or their feasibility even in
particularly weak regulatory environments, the WDR
argues that the Bank needs a more direct way to get
borrowing governments to adopt (what the Bank has
known all along to be) the right policy.
"Empirical studies show that aid finance is ineffective
in inducing policy reform in a bad policy environment.
What works better is choosing recipients more carefully,
based on performance (country selectivity) and setting
conditions that reward reforms completed rather than
those promised." (pp. 209-10)
Noting that conditionality doesn't work, the WDR proceeds
to endorse more coercive conditionality. A "bad
policy environment" exists where governments
(often pressured by citizens who do exercise voice)
resist reforms supported by the World Bank itself.
Sometimes those policies may be justified, such as
progressive budgeting. But more often they are liberalizing
policies that are known to be risky and difficult
to implement effectively. In any event, the WDR's
approach is not to scale back conditionality, but
rather to make it far more invasive than it has been
thus far. The report thus reinforces the World Bank's
message to borrowing governments: in order to qualify
for increased aid – or perhaps any aid –
you must comply with our policy conditions before
receiving resources, not after.
October 8, 2003.
[1] In a heroic
effort to synthesize these criteria, the authors produced
a tree diagram - modestly entitled "Eight Sizes
Fits All?" - which graphically locates policy
options. See Figure 7 in the Overview, p. 14.
[2] Richard Crook
and Alan Sverrisson, "Decentralisation and poverty-alleviation
in developing countries: a comparative analysis or,
is West Bengal unique?" IDS Working Paper 130,
February 2001.
[3] In "Ten
Years of Water Service Reform in Latin America: Towards
an Anglo-French Model" (forthcoming)
[4]
The problem of asymmetric information is at the heart
of the so-called "principal-agent problem."
Agents are supposed to work on behalf of principals:
CEOs work for company shareholders, sub-contractors
and private concessions work on behalf of government.
However, in practice, agents have much more information
about their activities than the principals they are
supposed to serve, and often withhold or manipulate
that information to promote their own rent-seeking
interests. The only way to make sufficient information
available to principals is through monitoring. When
monitoring becomes very costly or cannot be done adequately,
the principal needs to rethink their entire relationship
with the agent.
[5] I reality, much of the explanation
for why the past decade has seen so many privatizations
is direct pressure from the multilateral lenders,
such as conditionalities on adjustment loans or debt
relief. Governments also turn to privatization when
starved for public resources. The WDR team thus celebrates
as common sense the policies that have been imposed
on many of the Bank's borrowing members.
[6] The WDR advocates for a "short
route of accountability" between provider and
consumer policy-makers are not accountable to citizens.
However, if the World Bank took seriously the need
for citizen accountability, one might expect that
in the many privatization schemes it has financed,
that it would help governments design regulatory processes
that include disclosure to and input from citizens.
Yet there are few, if any, avenues for customer participation
in regulatory decisions and debates in the developing
world.
[7] Another condition is the inability
to use lifeline rates. However, as discussed above,
fiscal pressures often make progressive subsidies
impossible in practice, even if they are a good idea
in principle.
[8] This section was contributed
by Dave Hall, Director of Public Services International
Research Unit
[9] Judith Tendler, Good Government
in the Tropics . John Hopkins University Press, 1997
[10] A statement consistent with
the World Bank's rhetoric on "ownership"
might simply have read: "Policy-makers should
be encouraged to develop their own position on the
best way to deliver water and other services."
Such as statement would be made even more powerful
by adding: "The World Bank can support government
ownership by de-linking aid levels. from reform decisions.
|