Nhe
very fast growth of internal public debt in Brazil
since the inflation stabilisation plan of 1994 ("Plano
Real") is a direct consequence of the economic
policy decision to maintain extremely high domestic
interest rates for many years. The purpose of this
policy of "dear money" was to attract foreign
capital flows and keep the nominal exchange rate relatively
stable. This, in turn, was supposed to prevent cost
inflation and to obtain a real exchange rate revaluation,
which would provide the shock of foreign competition
to the formerly protected Brazilian industrial sector.
However, the effect has been rather different in practice:
an explosion of imports, ballooning of the current
account deficit, increasing net external liabilities
and the loss of competitiveness of Brazilian exports.
As a consequence, growth in the subsequent period
has been both mediocre and unstable.
Recently, it has become fashionable to argue that
the growth in internal public debt was a result of
an excessively expansionary fiscal policy in the first
term in office of President Cardoso (up to 1998).
However, as the average primary public sector deficit
(excluding interest payments) over the 1995-1998 period
was only 0.2% of GDP, this interpretation simply makes
no sense at all.
It is important to stress that there was no compelling
economic reason for the maintenance of such high domestic
rates of interest in the past. The Brazilian basic
domestic rate of interest has been kept for years
well above the sum of the international interest rate
plus the sovereign risk premium plus the market expected
rate of exchange devaluation (currency risk) that
determines the safe floor for nominal interest rates
in a context of high short-term capital mobility.
One reason that has been advanced for this policy
is that the interest rate was connected to the need
to contract credit, and, through its negative effect
on consumption expenditures and housing investment,
to reduce the expansion of the economy and the associated
further deterioration of the current account. This
explanation must be discarded. It would have been
easy to achieve this goal without entailing such a
high cost for the Treasury, through other measures
such as higher compulsory deposits by banks (which
act as a tax that increases the private loan rates
without affecting the basic rate paid by the government)
along with more realistic and less irresponsible tariff
and real exchange rate policies.
In Brazil, the high rate of interest is not caused
by the growth of internal debt. On the contrary, it
is the growth of internal public debt that is the
result of a policy decision of the Brazilian central
bank to keep very high interest rates.
It is important to bear in mind that, contrary to
fears, the record growth of the public debt did not
lead directly to any major adverse consequences. Rather,
the insistence that the internal debt should not be
growing (which was obviously incompatible with the
high real interest rate policy that added to the interest
burden so significantly) had the very unfortunate
consequence of making the Brazilian government focus
its fiscal policy exclusively on obtaining large and
growing primary fiscal surpluses at any cost.
Years of high real interest rates have discouraged
investment in the export sectors, which could not
pass the high financial costs to prices. In the non-tradeable
sectors, high real interest rates certainly have contributed
to the maintenance of very high gross profit margins
and to a worsening of the functional distribution
of income (the wage share fell below the share of
property income) and of the already very unequal distribution
of wealth.
More recently, the internal debt has continued to
grow for two reasons. While real interest rates are
lower than in the nineties, they remain quite high.
Also, an increasing proportion of internal debt bonds
is now indexed to the dollar exchange rate. With the
large real exchange rate devaluation since 1999 (and
especially in the last few months of instability)
the internal debt to GDP ratio has not stopped growing
despite the growing primary fiscal surpluses, which
have been obtained through massive increases in the
gross tax to GDP burden. It is highly improbable that
a fiscal reform, which is desirable in its own right
for distributive and export incentive reasons, could
lead to further substantial increases in the tax to
GDP ratio.
The problem of the internal debt thus comes from record
high real interest rates, slow growth of the economy
and, more recently, the excessively devalued exchange
rate relative to the dollar. The question is how to
reduce the rate of interest and stabilise the exchange
rate at a more sensible level, now that the country
has gone through yet another external liquidity crisis
and approached the IMF for more money.
Of course, it would be very difficult to drastically
reduce domestic interest rates overnight. Luckily,
this is by no means necessary. As already noted, the
growth of the internal public debt does not, by itself,
cause any big tragedy. Further, as long as the domestic
interest rate remains above the safe floor defined
above, there is no reason to fear capital flight and
a run for the dollar.
Thus, the domestic interest rate can be reduced gradually
as the determinants of the floor rate are reduced.
This process will make the internal debt ratio first
grow more slowly and then enter a sustainable trajectory,
without the need for large primary fiscal surpluses.
The sovereign risk spread will tend to fall substantially
if the newly elected government works seriously and
quickly towards import substitution and export promotion.
Currency risk can be greatly reduced if the central
bank amply supplies the market with dollar indexed
domestic bonds to meet its demand for an exchange
rate hedge, without having to use up its foreign reserves.
The central bank can also put much tougher capital
requirement margins on exchange rate speculation operations
by Brazilian banks.
In order to avoid these recurrent problems, it is
also important that in the future at least a minimum
of control in speculative capital inflows should be
introduced, something that could easily be done by
selective and differential taxation of undesirable
flows of foreign capital which, incidentally, are
often driven by Brazilian nationals sending money
to tax havens abroad.
In short, the problem of internal public debt in
Brazil comes primarily from very high real interest
rates. These can and will only fall substantially
if the government adopts suitable structural policies
that help to improve the basic balance of payments
situation.
October 16, 2002.
|