On
October 10, the Chinese government announced that
it will increase its stakes in the four largest commercial
banks, which are already largely public-owned. The
move is designed to ''support the healthy operations
and development of key state-owned financial institutions
and stabilise the share prices of state-owned commercial
banks''.
But why was this move considered necessary at all?
In the period just before this, investors were dumping
Chinese bank shares, anticipating a slowing down not
just of the economy as a whole, but in particular
the property market, which had experienced a bubble
of massive proportions. But the underlying concern
about the health of Chinese banks reflects a deeper
concern, about the extent of entanglement of these
commercial banks with the growing ''shadow banking
sector''.
What exactly is shadow banking? Basically, this refers
to non-depository banks and other financial entities
like investment banks, mutual funds, hedge funds,
money market funds and insurers, who typically do
not fall under banking regulation. The growth of this
sector has been explosive in the last decade: in the
United States, in the run-up to the financial crisis,
its size was estimated to be significantly bigger
than that of the formal banking sector. In the aftermath
of the crisis, many of these institutions, and banks
that were exposed to them, had to be rescued.
UNCTAD's Trade
and Development Report 2011 noted that ''The shadow
banking system depends on wholesale funding, which
is extremely unstable and renders the system very
fragile, as evidenced by the crisis'' (page 94). It
argued strongly in favour of bringing shadow banking
under regulation; not just money market mutual funds,
but also the asset-backed securities market financed
with repos.
Even at the IMF, a
recent meeting of regulators held during the Autumn
meetings called for greater regulatory focus on
shadow banking. Participants noted that shadow banking
operations, that firms doing these bank-like activities
outside the banking system can pose systemic threats,
and to have some effect regulators need more and different
data to understand this fast-changing sector.
But China was known to have a much more regulated
banking sector. Indeed, the ability of the Chinese
authorities to control the four important commercial
banks (Bank of China, Agricultural Bank of China,
China Construction Bank and Industrial and Commercial
Bank of China, which together were earlier estimated
to control more than three quarters of total domestic
credit) was seen as important macroeconomic tool in
the hands of the state as well as an instrument of
ensuring directed credit, both of which have been
crucial to China's economic success.
Before the 1978 reform, the financial system of China
was vastly different from that in most countries.
Starting from 1951, banks and other financial institutions
were taken over by the state and assimilated into
a system dominated by the People's Bank of China (PBC).
Until 1984 this system essentially implemented the
cash and credit plans formulated by the central authorities,
which supported the physical plan for mobilisation,
allocation and utilisation of real resources. All
public sector transactions, including those between
various levels of government and the state enterprises,
were through transfers on their accounts with the
PBC. These account transfers at the PBC accounted
for an overwhelming share (of up to 95 per cent) of
all transactions.
Moreover, cash (to serve the needs of households and
non-state owned enterprises) was printed and issued
by the PBC on demand by the central government and
allocated according to instructions issued. The main
elements of money in circulation were wage payments
to workers and staff, the purchase of agricultural
products by the government, other purchases of goods
in the rural sector, and the withdrawing of savings
deposits by individuals. The banking system was not
responsible for provision of resources for fixed asset
investments by the state owned enterprises (SOEs)
and for much of their working capital requirements,
which were made available free of charge by the Ministry
of Finance. The banking system was merely responsible
for providing additional working capital and some
loans, for accepting deposits from households and
other non-government entities and for settlement of
transactions.
There was little role for monetary policy, since credit
provision was centralised and strictly controlled.
Enterprises and other economic entities received grants
and loans directly from the PBC. Bank branches had
to merely meet credit targets. And lower level banking
entities had to hand over deposits that exceeded their
credit provision targets to higher-level units. If
the government felt the need for restricting economic
activity, it did so directly through administrative
means rather than using levers of monetary policy.
To manage the supply of cash and its utilisation,
the central authorities could adjust (administered)
prices relative to money wages (using a turnover tax
if necessary). However, since the objective was to
keep prices mostly stable, excess cash in circulation
was absorbed through rationing, when commodity supplies
fell short of demand, and by encouraging savings.
Financial reform created a situation in which banks,
financial institutions and enterprises at provincial
and local levels had more flexibility in providing
and accessing loans, so the ability of the government
to control sharp increases in investment and consumption
was to an extent reduced. So the government has increasingly
relied more on countercyclical fiscal policy to correct
for recessionary or inflationary tendencies. Meanwhile,
price reform has meant that a growing number of commodities
have been removed from the administered price category,
so that excess demand can lead to inflation.
In the early phases of the economic reform, along
with price reform, certain significant changes were
made in the financial field as well. In 1979, the
government declared its intention to reduce the share
of investment funds for enterprises granted exclusively
from the cost-free state budget, and to gradually
replace budgetary grants with bank loans which were
subject to interest charges. This did result in major
changes in the financing of investment. The share
of budgetary appropriations in financing capital construction
declined dramatically and that of loans and self-raised
funds increased quite significantly.
A two-tiered banking system was established in 1984
by converting the PBC into the country's central bank
and getting the specialised banks to undertake the
commercial banking business. Further in 1986, reform
of the non-bank financial sector resulted in the creation
of a number of trust and investment companies, and
financial intermediaries such as leasing companies,
pension funds and insurance companies. Subsequently,
foreign banks were allowed to begin business for the
first time.
However, even under the new arrangement it was in
principle possible for the PBC to rein in overdrafts
being run by these banks and prevent them from exceeding
loan limits or quotas. Further, now the PBC could
control the terms of its lending by charging lower
rates of interest for loans within the credit plan
and penalize unauthorised borrowing. Thus the ability
of the PBC to realize its credit plan was strengthened
by the reform.
However, with a greater degree of decentralisation
of financial activity and the ability of local officials
to influence provincial and local appointments in
the banks, it was possible for provincial and local
governments to easily obtain finance for special projects
adding another element to the investment hunger determined
by soft budget constraints in the SOE sector. Over
time this problem has only increased with an increase
in the number of financial entities, a change in property
rights in the financial sector and a far greater degree
of functional autonomy. In the process, the capacity
of the central bank to use monetary levers to control
investment expenditures is weakened.
The changes accelerated after 2008, when the urge
to provide more stimulus meant that the government
allowed or encouraged more ''informal'' credit flows
that went through new shadow banking intermediaries.
As a result, the government's control over actual
flows of domestic liquidity is weaker than it has
been for more than half a century. In addition to
trust companies and private banks, which are not regulated
but at least are registered businesses with established
offices, there has been a proliferation of underground
operators, usually no better than loan sharks operating
in a world of largely unsecured loans. Such has been
the profitability of these operations that even large
local state-owned firms whose main business was not
finance are now expanding into operating guarantee
companies, pawnshops and trusts, arbitraging their
own access to cheap loans to lend out at many multiples
of the official interest rates.
On the face of it, China's household sector appears
to be not excessively leveraged at all - rather, they
are substantial net financial savers, as Chart 1 indicates.
Unfortunately, however, China's official financial
statistics still do not cover shadow banking entities,
though there are plans to reform the statistical system
to being these under the purview of the data collection.
But even without these, the data indicate that the
ratio of liabilities to assets has been rising quite
rapidly.
The growing but opaque interlinkages between the
formal credit system and the world of shadow banking
are cause for concern. This is because the formal
banks are also more attracted to indirect lending
that generates at least double or triple the official
6.5 per cent one-year lending rate, and can even go
up to 30-70 per cent in underground banks. The most
profitable activity of state-owned banks in the first
half of 2011 was not lending to businesses, but funding
trusts and underground banks.
Much of that went into the overheated housing market,
associated not just with a construction boom but with
urban real estate prices that are now the highest
in the world for cities like Shanghai and Beijing.
Chart 2 shows that even formally, direct loans from
Chinese banks for real estate and housing increased
significantly in the previous two years.
But these relate only to the direct lending by banks.
Increasingly, commercial banks find it more profitable
to lend to other agencies, which then redirect the
funds in this parallel or shadow banking activity
that demands much higher interest rates. Chart 3 shows
how this became a significant and even increasing
share of banking assets especially for the small and
medium sized Chinese banks. The chart takes claims
on ''other depository corporations'', ''other financial
corporations'' and ''other resident sectors'' (excluding
non-financial corporations, government and central
bank) as shares of total assets of banks according
to size. This is only an approximate estimation of
the shadow banking sector, since these categories
also include other lending. But some analysts have
already estimated that the value of China's shadow
banking sector could amount to as much as RMB 14 to
15 trillion.
Since official curbs on lending to this sector were
tightened in early 2011, this parallel market expanded
even further. However, the tighter interest rate policies
and credit curbs have finally affected the real estate
market. Recently the market has wobbled and real estate
prices have finally started falling.
The bursting of this bubble could be painful. In an
attempt to provide some protection, the government
has encouraged the growth of credit guarantee companies
- but many of these are also highly leveraged and
themselves far from creditworthy.
For a very long time, China's ability to control finance
was an important (some would say essential) ingredient
of its macroeconomic success. Now that this control
looks more tenuous, the future of the overall growth
strategy also looks that much less rosy.
* This article was originally
published in the Business Line, 31 October, 2011.
November
1, 2011.
|