It
is a proposal that refuses to die. When Finance Ministers
of the overactive G20 met at St Andrews, Scotland
in early November, the UK's Prime Minister Gordon
Brown decided to use what would be the last meeting
under his presidency to make a case for taxing finance.
His argument was simple. Over the last two years,
fragility or failure in the banking system has necessitated
using tax payers' money to bail out banks. And the
evidence seems to be that once the losses of banks
resulting from the speculative fervour of managers
in search of bonuses had been absorbed and their capital
base refurbished, these managers or their replacements
have gone back to playing the same game and earning
similar bonuses, keeping the prospect of future failure
alive. It is obviously unjust and even infeasible
to repeatedly call upon the public at large to pay
for the errors, forced or unforced, of the bankers.
So post-crisis financial reform, Brown had argued,
must include measures that require banks to pay for
the (extremely high) likelihood that their actions
would burden tax payers with the costs of rescuing
banks in future. In words that caught the world's
attention he said: "It cannot be acceptable that the
benefits of success in [banking] are reaped by the
few but the costs of its failure are borne by all
of us". Impeccable logic, anyone would say.
There were four such measures to deal with the problem
that Brown had tentatively advanced. One was an extension
of the current remedy of forcing banks to provide
for potential losses in advance. World governments
should consider requiring banks whose failure was
seen as being systemically damaging to hold more capital
to cover potential losses than required of other less
systemically relevant banks. However, if the crisis
has taught us anything, it is that this idea of differential
levels of "capital adequacy" would take us nowhere.
If systemically risky banks are to provision for a
higher level of losses, the question that would arise
is how high is "higher"? This is because, as became
clear from banks' involvement with the shadow banking
system through on- and off-balance sheet transactions,
managers seeking to increase profits would siphon
money into the less regulated and more profitable
entities so as to earn revenues they cannot legitimately
seek. The higher is the pre-emption of their resources
for insurance purposes, the greater would be the desire
to indulge in such activity. In the event, if and
when the more risky banks fail the ripple effects
would engulf the systemically risky institutions as
well, and whatever level of capital adequacy is specified
may prove inadequate. Therefore, as Nouriel Roubini,
among others, still argues: "The true solution to
the too-big-to-fail problem requires more radical
choices. In addition to an insolvency regime, such
institutions should be broken up and unsecured creditors
of insolvent institutions should have their claim
automatically converted into equity. A separation
of commercial banking and risky investment banking
should also be considered. Thus, some variant of the
Glass-Steagall Act should be reintroduced."
Two other variants of the insurance scheme were advanced
by Gordon Brown and were also non-controversial, even
if not likely to be immediately taken up. One was
the creation of a pool of money financed by banks
and/or their customers that could be used to finance
orderly bail-outs as and when required. And the other
was mandating contingent capital requirements or the
holding of assets whose value or benefit is realised
only when an event that is uncertain occurs. These
are measures similar to deposit insurance, excepting
that it is not just depositors who are insured but
the banks themselves. The difficulty with these schemes
is that there is no guarantee that they would provide
adequately for the costs of a failure. The advantage
they have is that they are likely to garner international
support, since they limit, while leaving open, the
burden that would be imposed on financial institutions
today to meet costs that may have to be met tomorrow.
From the point of view of finance there is ample scope
to negotiate and render these costs small enough to
bear for institutions that are too big to fail.
In the event, the really controversial of Brown's
proposals was his fourth option of imposing a tax
on financial transactions that could either be used
to create a contingency fund or be spent on socially
beneficial projects so that taxpayers are compensated
today for any costs they may be called upon to bear
in future. The idea is not new and was, therefore,
immediately labelled the "Tobin Tax", even though
it differs significantly from the tax on foreign currency
transactions that was proposed by Nobel Prize winning
economist James Tobin. After the collapse of the Bretton
Woods agreement and the shift to floating exchange
rates in the early 1970s, Tobin proposed a small levy
on transactions in foreign exchange markets to discourage
speculation and endow currency markets with a degree
of stability. The proposal, which was questioned by
some who felt that it attempted to throw grains of
sand in the wheels of finance when what was required
were boulders, was never taken up because it needed
to be implemented by all countries simultaneously
if it was to be successful. Belgium did subsequently
pass a law to implement a Tobin-type tax, but made
its implementation contingent on a similar law being
adopted in all countries in the euro zone. But that
was not to be, since such consensus was lacking.
However, the idea was revived after the Southeast
Asian financial crisis of 1997, when it became clear
that once restrictions were removed on cross-border
flows of financial capital, speculative flows seeking
to profit from differentials in the rates of return
across countries and sectors could result in boom-bust
cycles with severely damaging consequences for the
real economy. The idea of the tax, while retaining
the Tobin label, was extended to curb speculative
capital flows by reducing their profitability and
was promoted by stating that the revenues collected
from such a tax could be used to further development
in the world's poorest countries. In the process,
support for the Tobin tax was substantially enhanced
and was seen as akin to opposition to policies and
institutions (such as the World Bank and the IMF)
that were for reduced controls on private capital
movements across borders. In fact, Tobin distanced
himself from the "anti-globalisation rebels" who he
complained had hijacked his name for wrong ends.
However, the wider support for Tobin-tax Mark II notwithstanding,
little progress was achieved. It was, not surprisingly,
opposed by finance. It was also opposed by countries
which felt that imposing such a tax, when others were
not opting for it, would drive capital out of their
countries and/or undermine their existing role or
potential role as global financial centres. And once
again the debate on the need for and feasibility of
such a tax petered out.
However, since financial crises do not disappear but
only recur, often with greater intensity, in contemporary
capitalism, the idea was bound to survive. We are
therefore witnessing now the revival of Tobin tax
Mark III in the wake of the global financial and economic
crisis of 2008. In August 2009, when an effort was
still underway to redirect attention from stalling
the recession to reforming finance, a person of no
less significance than Adair Turner, chairman of Britain's
Financial Services Authority and author of the much
discussed Turner Review of the implications of the
financial crisis, argued in an interview published
in Prospect magazine that the debate on bankers' bonuses
has become a "populist diversion" and that
more drastic measures may be needed to cut the financial
sector down to size. One such measure was a Tobin-type
tax on financial profits. "If you want to stop
excessive pay in a swollen financial sector you have
to reduce the size of that sector or apply special
taxes to its pre-remuneration profit," he said.
Coming from the chief of the financial watchdog in
the country that is home to the City of London (the
second most important global financial market after
New York), this was a significant statement. It showed
that at least some people responsible for the operations
of the City were not going to protect finance at all
cost in order to retain the competitiveness of the
City as a global financial centre. In fact, Turner
reportedly held that the FSA should "be very,
very wary of seeing the competitiveness of London
as a major aim", since the City had become a
destabilising influence in the British economy.
It was not surprising that Turner's statements generated
a backlash. According to the Financial Times (August
27, 2009): "A chief economist at a big bank described
the suggestion internally as "a stupid idea", while
an executive at one European bank said: "Global taxes
don't happen. Unless next month's G20 meeting can
suddenly pull something out of the hat, this will
be largely ignored."
The London meeting did indeed ignore the proposal,
even though there were hints of support from France
and elsewhere. But come November and the Turner-Tobin
proposal gained new momentum with Prime Minister Gordon
Brown weighing in for it. He, however, made it clear
that Britain would consider adopting the tax only
if the initiative was global. And, as expected, not
long after Brown's speech US Treasury Secretary Tim
Geithner made clear that the US was not willing to
support a financial transaction tax. Canada, Russia
and others, besides the IMF and the European Central
Bank, have joined the group of dissenters, increasing
the probability that the proposal will be shelved
once again.
In the circumstance many argue that Brown's declaration
of support for a financial transactions tax move may
just be his last effort to gain populist mileage from
the presidency of the G20 and shore up his waning
image at home. However, his actions have given a lease
of life to an idea that just will not go away. Turner's
assessment that the logic that "more complete markets
were good and more liquid markets are definitionally
good" is no longer trusted, and that the crisis "requires
a very major reconstruct of the global financial regulatory
system, [not] a minor adjustment," cannot be easily
ignored. Hence the proposal for a Tobin-type financial
transactions tax is likely to remain on the table.
November
25, 2009.
|