There
are many reasons to celebrate the award of the Nobel
Peace Prize for 2006 jointly to Muhammad Yunus, the
recognised creator of the "microcredit"
model of finance for the poor that has swept across
the developing world, and to the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh
that he founded three decades ago. These reasons go
well beyond appreciation of the valuable human qualities
of the man himself, such as his creativity, persistence,
charisma and passionate advocacy in promoting this
model widely and extending it in various ways. The
reasons for celebration also go beyond regional pride
– as South Asians, or even as citizens of the developing
world in general.
One important reason, of course, is that awards such
as this rescue the Nobel Peace Prize both from the
controversial dogfights that have accompanied some
of the political choices of the past, and from being
mired in a very restrictive notion of the concept
of peace. This award, along with the earlier award
to the African environmentalist Wangari Maathai, shows
the Nobel Committee's recognition that peace is not
really possible without more equitable development.
The citation says as much, claiming that this prize
is being given to Yunus and the Grameen Bank "for
their efforts to create economic and social development
from below. Lasting peace can not be achieved unless
large population groups find ways in which to break
out of poverty."
But while this is clearly a much-deserved prize, it
also exposes other weaknesses about Nobel Prizes in
general. It is in some ways a safe, even predictable,
choice. Rumours about this award have been in wide
circulation for some time, given the now almost universal
espousal of microcredit by the World Bank and international
development agencies in general, as well as by many
developing country governments. The UN declared 2005
to be "the international year of microcredit",
and there has been enthusiastic promotion in international
circles by Bill Clinton and others.
Tit is worth noting is that the economist Dr. Muhammad
Yunus received this prize for promoting peace, rather
than the Nobel Prize for Economics. Yet his contribution
has really been in the field of economics, since his
model stood conventional economic theory on its head
and effectively created a new paradigm, which has
since spawned an international industry of theoretical
models to explain its success. This tells us something
about how relatively limited in vision the awards
of the Economics Nobel Prize have been. They have
focussed much more on narrow academic peer recognition
than on addressing real world development issues or
processes that actually transform economies.
What exactly was this innovation called microcredit?
To understand its significance, it is important to
begin with understanding how formal financial institutions
operate. Since giving credit is always associated
with some risk of default – that is, the borrower
not returning the loan amount or paying interest –
bankers of all types usually require some form of
surety (collateral) against which they can lend. Formal
banking institutions therefore require the borrower
to have some assets like land or a house, or a secure
job, or a certified credit history, or some such assurance
against which they will proffer funds.
This obviously eliminates the poor, who are by definition
without significant assets and usually also lack secure
streams of income through regular employment. So the
poor get automatically excluded from formal financial
institutions, and are forced to go to private moneylenders
who charge very high rates of interest. These traditional
moneylenders are able to function in such circumstances
because they can somehow ensure that the loan and
interest are repaid through extra-economic means,
or can extract other forms of payment such a labour
services.
It was therefore accepted that the poor were not "bankable"
for formal financial institutions, or able to access
other financial services such as insurance. Economic
theory had also devised many complicated models to
explain the necessary persistence of traditional money
lending and high interest rates among the poor.
The significance of the Grameen Bank and other microcredit
experiments was that they countered this axiomatic
belief by showing that even formal financial institutions
could provide loans exclusively to the poor and still
be assured of repayment. This is because they are
based on the principle of "group lending"
whereby loans are made to a group (of between 5 and
20 people) and therefore peer pressure acts as an
effective mode of ensuring repayment.
Muhammad Yunus may not be the pioneer of microcredit
– there were cases of similar experiments in the early
1970s in Colombia and Brazil, for example. But he
was the first to make this a viable model capable
of being copied and scaled up, and he also became
a tireless propagator of the cause of microcredit
worldwide.
It all began in 1974, during a famine in Bangladesh,
when Yunus was teaching economics at Chittagong University
after receiving a doctorate in the US. In his efforts
to do something to help the famine-ravaged people
in the district, he was visiting nearby villages when
he was persuaded to make his first loan in the village
of Jobra.
He offered around 7000 Bangladeshi taka from his own
funds to a group of 42 bamboo craftspeople in desperate
need. They had no collateral to offer, and no contract
was signed. Nevertheless, the loan was repaid in full,
after the borrowers used the money to buy bamboo,
sell their crafts and repay both Yunus and the traditional
moneylenders to whom they were indebted.
Yunus drew from this the lesson that the poor can
indeed be viable and creditworthy borrowers. But his
efforts to persuade banks to lend to them independently
were fruitless, as the banks all continued to insist
on his personal surety for any loans taken by those
without collateral. In any case, traditional banks
were simply not interested in making tiny loans at
high transaction cost to those with no credit history.
The Grameen Bank was founded in 1976 by Muhammad Yunus
as a result of such experience. It was dedicated to
serving the poorest of the poor, based on Yunus' vision
that even such very poor people were viable credit
risks and could make productive use of small loans
to enhance their earning capacity.
The Grameen bank model that emerged had some important
features, apart from its concentration on the poor
as clients. It involved lending in groups (originally
of five members) who were jointly responsible for
the loan. It required repayment in small periodic
instalments, over a relatively short period. It lent
not only to farmers but also to rural labourers, petty
traders, and most importantly to women. While at first
male borrowers outnumbered their female counterparts,
this was consciously altered so that by the mid 1980s
women accounted for more than 96 per cent of the loans.
This aspect of lending to women has emerged as one
of the more transformatory features of the Grameen
model. Women turned out to be much more reliable borrowers,
whose loans were used for the well-being of the family.
But this also became an important instrument of social
change in the conservative patriarchal context of
Bangladeshi society. Not only did the access to microfinance
improve women's bargaining power within their households,
but the fact of meeting together and being part of
groups led to other ways of thinking in a collective
mode that proved to be quite empowering.
These features have been emulated not only by BRAC
(Bangladesh Rural Action Committee) and Proshikha,
the two other large microcredit NGOs in Bangladesh,
but across the world, as the focus on microcredit
has been an important part of the agenda of multilateral
development banks and even of governments. And the
focus on women borrowers has proved to be one of the
more successful results of the model wherever it has
been transplanted.
The spread of this essentially simple idea has been
quite remarkable in the past two decades. According
to the 2005 "State of the Microcredit Summit
Campaign Report", at the end of 2004 there were
3,200 microcredit institutions that reported reaching
more than 92 million clients across the world.
In India too, governments at central and state levels
have been actively promoting microcredit, particularly
to women, through the institution of Self Help Groups
which engage in both savings and loan activities.
In some states such as Karnataka and Andhra Pradesh,
such organisations has been present for some time
now, through the efforts of NGOs such as Mahila Samakhya
and Co-operative Development Foundation.
A further innovation has been to form them into federations
and link them with formal lending institutions. NABARD
(the National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development)
has a scheme whereby it finances more than 500 nationalised
banks for lending on to Self Help Groups that have
shown they can manage their funds well. The amounts
involved are relatively small and the interest rates
are also quite high (usually around 12 per cent).
Bu the scheme involves very large numbers – around
1.4 millions SHGs comprising nearly 20 million women,
making this Indian scheme therefore the largest bank-microcredit
linkage in the world.
Despite this spread, and some clear areas of success,
it is a mistake to view microcredit as the universal
development panacea which it seems to have become
for the international development industry. It can
at best be a part of a wider process that also includes
working towards reducing asset inequalities, better
and more egalitarian access to health and education
services, more productive employment opportunities.
The undoubted successes of the microcredit model should
not blind us to some of the problems and concerns
that have been expressed. It still remains difficult
to make microcredit a commercially viable proposition
for finance institutions. Even in Bangladesh, Grameen
Bank and BRAC still depend substantially on subsidies
to run their operations despite the high repayment
rates, because of high costs of transaction and monitoring.
Supporters argue that it is better to spend public
money on such subsidies rather than on other forms
of public expenditure, since it is cost-effective
and responsive to local felt needs.
Yet it is also true that the amounts of money distributed
through microcredit are so small and the periods for
repayment are so short, that they cannot really lead
to effective asset building. Some argue that microcredit
at best acts as a consumption stabiliser, reducing
the adverse effects of shocks such as natural calamities
or seasonal fluctuations, and provides means for taking
advantage of very small business opportunities. In
the absence of other measures or more dynamic growth
processes, this can amount to no more than a redistribution
of incomes among the relatively poor, rather than
an overall increase in incomes of the poor. It can
also be associated with microcredit dependency, involving
continued reliance on loans for consumption rather
than put to productive use.
Similarly, the group lending that delivers high repayment
rates can also become an instrument of stratification,
especially when there are linkages with banks providing
some additional institutional finance to the groups.
There have been cases of women from the most destitute
or socially deprived groups being excluded from membership
of groups containing better off members, because of
fears that their inability to repay will damage the
prospects of other members. In some states of India,
peer pressure has forced women borrowers to take on
expensive loans from moneylenders to repay the loans
from the Self Help Group.
A more damaging argument suggests that microcredit
programmes can have adverse effects if they imply
a transfer of public resources from other public spending,
leading to cuts in public health, sanitation and education
expenditure. This need not happen, but if it does,
then it is akin to a privatisation of public welfare
programmes, with unclear effects on overall development.
Further, a focus on microcredit should not reduce
public attention to ensure adequate institutional
finance to rural areas in general, such as agricultural
loans and loans to small businesses.
All these criticisms do not detract from the importance
of the microcredit model, but they do emphasise that
this in itself cannot be seen as the magic bullet
to end rural poverty. To their credit, both Muhammad
Yunus and the Grameen Bank themselves appear to be
aware of this rather obvious truth, since their interventions
over the past decades have been characterised by continuous
innovation and experimentation. In addition to other
forms of microfinance such as insurance, Grameen has
experimented with housing loans, loans for fisheries
and other small enterprises, venture capital, solar
energy projects, a commercial telecom project with
a Norwegian partner to deliver cheap rural phones,
and now even health care services.
It is this approach, of constantly listening to the
actual needs of the poor, of being flexible in terms
of continuously looking for new solutions and enlarging
possibilities from below, which is the most engaging
aspect of Muhammad Yunus' contribution. Even more
than microcredit alone, it may turn out to be his
most positive influence.
November 6, 2006.
|