In
the run up to the Hong Kong WTO Ministerial, the focus
of attention is the deadlock over liberalisation of
agriculture. This is not surprising, given the fact
that the unwillingness of EU members, especially France,
to agree to "adequate" concessions on agricultural
tariffs and subsidies, has stalled negotiations on
further liberalisation of trade in areas outside of
agriculture. What is disturbing, however, is the perception
purveyed by the negotiators, government spokespersons
and the media that once the agriculture deadlock is
resolved, the task of moving the Doha Round forward
is rendered easy: that is, the prospect of getting
the developing countries to agree to substantial liberalisation
of the trade in industrial goods and services is seen
as extremely bright.
This is disconcerting because the walls of protection
built by developing countries since the Great Depression
and during the years of decolonisation, to overcome
the debilitating effects of international inequality,
were predominantly in these areas. Protection was
seen in the first instance as the means to build an
indigenous industrial base, thereby ensuring the structural
diversification needed in predominantly agricultural
economies to garner productivity gains and obtain
a sustainable position within the unequal international
division of labour. But, more importantly it was recognised
as the means to carve out the necessary domestic policy
space within which national governments could pursue
their own economic and social objectives.
It is indeed true that in the wave of liberalisation
and globalisation, which saw domestic elites in the
Third World scrambling to attract international capital
in a desperate attempt to overcome the constraints
to their own expansion set by the failure to introduce
the institutional reforms needed to expand domestic
markets and trigger domestic investment, much of this
protection has been dismantled. But rather than learn
the lessons delivered by the deindustrialisation that
this process of liberalisation has spurred, the effort
seem to be to accept the intensification and institutionalisation
of such liberalisation that the developed countries
are seeking to achieve through the WTO and the Doha
Round.
A typical example of this is, of course. the negotiations
on non-agricultural market access (NAMA). The NAMA
negotiations, mandated under the Doha ministerial
declaration of November 2001, are aimed at reducing
border restrictions to trade such as tariffs and other
barriers to market access for industrial exports.
The negotiations cover all goods not covered under
the Agreement on Agriculture. Since 2002, NAMA negotiators
have sought to establish modalities or rules specifying
how and to what extent a country should reduce their
trade barriers. At the 2003 Cancun ministerial conference,
conference chairman and Mexican trade minister Luis
Ernesto Derbez submitted a text, commonly known as
the "Derbez Text," proposing a framework for modalities
in NAMA.
The Derbez text reflects the objectives of the developed
countries with regard to increasing non-agricultural
market access. As argued by Yilmaz Akyuz, former Director
of the Division on Globalization and Development Strategies,
UNCTAD, these objectives are of four kinds. The first,
is to ensure that ultimately tariffs on all product
lines should be bound or subject to a maximum ceiling,
constraining across-the-board the ability of developing
countries to exercise the tariff protection option
to foster or expand particular industries. This is
of significance because unlike the developed countries
in whose case almost all industrial products are subject
to a ceiling, a large number of products, particularly
in the case of the African countries, are still not
covered by tariff binds. In fact, coverage in the
case of as many as 30 countries is less than 35 per
cent. Binding tariffs obviously reduces policy flexibility
substantially, inasmuch as these maximum levels set
a ceiling on what developing countries can do to protect
an industry they choose to develop at some point in
the future.
The second objective seems to be a continuous process
of trade liberalisation culminating in a situation
where trade is near-completely free. This requires
that the liberalisation and tariff reduction achieved
during the Uruguay Round is advanced further through
tariff reduction in the Doha Round. In fact, Annex
B even proposes a sectoral initiative where WTO members
select several products for complete tariff elimination,
also called "zero-for-zero" reductions.
The third and related objective is to reduce tariff
dispersion across countries. The intention is to reduce
the current 11 percentage point difference in average
weighted bound tariffs between developed (3 per cent)
and developing (14 per cent) countries, initially
to around 4 per cent and finally to zero. The absurdity
of believing that in an obviously unequal global industrial
environment the extent of protection must be homogenised
should be obvious. That belief is even more absurd
when judged in the context of evidence that all developed
countries used protection as the means to industrialize
in their early stage of development, and continue
to do so even now.
Finally, the intention is to reduce tariff dispersion
across tariff lines by forcing a greater proportionate
reduction in tariffs in the case of products currently
protected with higher tariffs. Since it is known that
in an increasingly diversified economic world complete
insularity is not an option open to any country, this
measure undermines the ability of countries to adopt
strategies that focus on fostering and developing
individual industries.
Given these objectives embedded in the Derbez text
and the strength of the developed countries, it is
not surprising that the NAMA negotiations are centred
on the extent of binding coverage and the formula
to be used for tariff reduction. The text seeks to
combine increased binding with a single "non-linear"
tariff-reduction formula. The latter is designed to
ensure larger proportionate reductions in tariffs
in countries and sectors with higher tariffs in order
to realize the homogenization agenda. The intent of
the exercise was clear from the fact that this "Swiss
formula" is often referred to as "the harmonizing
formula" inasmuch as it is a move towards uniform
tariff structures across different sectors and countries.
The real implication of this process of harmonisation
emerges once we consider the following facts that
(i) developing countries have seen in recent years
a process of "tariffication" or the replacement of
import quotas on industrial imports with tariffs,
making the latter the principal protectionist device;
(ii) developed countries are known to rely on non-tariff
barriers and special safeguards in the case of sensitive
products (such as textiles) rather than tariffs to
protect their industries and therefore are not too
concerned with pure tariff protection; and (iii) as
expected, developing countries are characterised in
most areas by much higher tariffs rates than the developed
countries, so that the effective increase in market
access associated with any particular proportionate
reduction in tariffs would be far greater in developing
countries than in the developed-a 50 per cent reduction
of a 20 per cent tariff rate would bring it down by
10 percentage points, whereas it would imply a mere
two percentage point reduction in the case of a four
per cent tariff.
Following the failure at Cancun and the subsequent
opposition from developing countries, including India,
which supported the African group, the text Derbez
was not accepted. However, in an enforced compromise,
it was included as Annex B in the July Framework of
2004 with the caveat that "additional negotiations
... on the specifics of some of these elements" were
required. These 'specifics', though inadequately specified,
were to "relate to the formula, the issues concerning
treatment of unbound tariffs…the flexibilities for
developing country participants, (and) the issue of
participation in the sectoral tariff component preferences."
This kept the Derbez text as the base for negotiations,
while providing a window of opportunity to the developing
countries to minimize the concessions they would have
to offer in this area.
However, the more developed among the developing are,
it now appears, not averse to making significant concessions.
In a proposal submitted in April this year, Argentina,
Brazil and India (ABI) advanced and therefore signalled
acceptance of a non-linear Swiss-type formula for
line-by-line tariff reduction for all bound tariff
rates. They have also to differing degrees accepted
the demand to bind unbound tariff lines. This move
has been defended on the grounds that average tariffs
are in any case low in the developed countries and
declining in the developing countries, and what really
matters is the problem of tariff peaks (excessively
high tariffs) and tariff escalation (higher tariffs
on end products rather than inputs) in the developed
countries that militate against developing country
exports. Thus a Swiss-type formula applied on a line-by-line
basis is expected to deliver substantial benefits
to developing country exporters, in areas of interest
to them, by dealing with the problem of tariff peaks
and tariff escalation in the developed countries.
What is ignored is the possibility that anti-dumping
measures, non-tariff barriers especially technical
barriers to trade can be used to neutralise these
supposed benefits. Meanwhile, developing countries
would be opening up their own markets to competition
from imports.
This move on the part of the ABI group, besides being
a unilateral gesture advanced with the hope, but no
guarantee, of obtaining concessions in areas such
as agriculture and services that are seen as promising
substantial benefits to them, completely undermines
the ostensible 'development-oriented' mandate of the
Doha Round. Since Doha was intended to advance a development
agenda, the focus of the NAMA negotiations was to
be on the elimination of tariff peaks and tariff escalation
on products of export interest to developing countries,
without reciprocal offers in their own markets. In
fact, governments had on paper agreed that they would
take into account the special needs and interests
of developing countries. By making their offer, the
ABI group has paved the way for a retreat of the developed
countries on the question of Special and Differential
Treatment (SDT) and "less than full reciprocity" and
also paved the way for a degree of erosion of trade
preferences, excepting perhaps for the Least Developed
Countries.
There are a number of consequences that can be expected
to follow from these developments. First, the nonlinear
formula approach denies the current day developing
countries from the instruments used by the developed
countries at similar stages of development. Those
countries used tariffs as an important instrument
to protect certain products and allow access for others.
Second, as argued earlier, by increasing their tariff
bindings, developing countries would be forced to
forgo some ?exibility in economic policy. As Martin
Khor and Goh Chien Yen have argued, "a developing
country needs to be able to modulate the tariffs on
various types of products on a dynamic basis to support
its upgradation of industrial production. It may need
to have lower tariffs on certain products, for example
machines, for some time to encourage their use in
the production of downstream products. But after some
time, these tariffs may need to be raised when the
country embarks on producing the former product, e.g.,
the machines in this example, in order to protect
its newly emerging machine-building industry. If a
commitment for binding of tariffs on machines has
already been made, such raising of tariffs will not
be possible without compensation."
Third, the total elimination of tariffs negotiated
under the sectoral initiative will make it virtually
impossible to set up industries in those sectors in
the future. Fourth, reducing tariffs leads to a loss
of public revenue for governments in developing countries.
Tariff revenue contributed 32 percent of total government
revenue in least-developed countries in 2001.
All of this is of significance, not only because the
process of tarffication has made tariffs the most
important protective device, but also because the
Uruguay Round has ensured that through clauses in
the Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPs)
agreement and the Trade Related Investment Measures
(TRIMs) agreed upon, developing countries have lost
the right to use measures such as denial of product
patents and insistence on indigenous content requirements
as a means of fostering and developing an indigenous
industrial base. Since the evidence from close to
two decades of globalisation make clear that foreign
investors are no substitute for domestic firms when
it comes to ensuring diversification of output and
employment in favour of industry, this tendency in
the NAMA negotiations is essentially a way of institutionalising
through an international agreement the process of
deindustrialisation in the developing world.
November 18, 2005.
|