One
of the myths about globalisation that has been systematically
punctured over the past decade is that it would lead
to greater convergence of incomes between countries.
In fact the period after 2000 has been one of even
more uneven development in the world economy than
in the past.
It has become evident that those analyses that still
try to peddle this line rely essentially on the fast
economic growth of China and to a lesser extent India,
who together make up more than one-third of the world’
population. And even so, greater rural-urban inequality
within these two countries makes a completely optimistic
result hard o establish.
However, on the question of the convergence between
the richest and poorest countries, it would be impossible
to have a debate. The data is unambiguous that the
poorest and least developed countries (hereafter LDCs)
have not performed well over this period, and the
gap between them and both the richest and the middle
income countries has grown substantially.
Of course, it is true that even among LDCs, there
has been a wide distribution of outcomes. For example,
the best performer, Bangladesh, grew at a very respectable
annual rate of 2.6 per cent per capita between 1980
and 2002, while the worst performers (Djibouti, Sierra
Leone, Haiti) all had per capita income losses of
between 40 and 50 per cent. But there were only three
clearly good performers among LDCs: Bangladesh, Lesotho
and Uganda. The group of LDCs as a whole shows no
movement towards higher per capita incomes and nearly
half of them had negative growth rates.
What explains this growing divergence? What are LDCs
not only failing to catch up, but even experiencing
patterns of growth that widen the gap between them
and richer countries? A recent study by the economist
Branko Milanovic (''Why did the poorest countries fail
to catch up?'', Carnegie Papers No 62, Trade Equity
and Development Project, Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace, 2005) tries to identify the factors.
This study at least helps to establish what was not
responsible. Mainstream economists, when faced with
such reality, have a typical response: ''The reforms
have been too slow, or too limited, or not deep enough.''
But Milanovic shows that even when ''reforms'' (which
are basically more neoliberal policies) have been
slower or less extensive than in other middle income
developing countries, this could have played at best
a minimal role. In fact, even this limited conclusion
is unwarranted, since Milanovic suggests that neoliberal
reforms in these countries started a decade after
those in middle income countries, whereas actually
most LDCs (especially those in Sub-Saharan Africa
and Central or Latin America) have been engaged in
policies of privatisation and liberalisation from
the early 1980s, typically due to pressure from multilateral
aid institutions.
Similarly, the study shows that the LDCs did at least
as much trade liberalisation as other countries. The
average level of protection measured by tariff rates
is not different for LDCs than it is for other countries,
so this too is unlikely to have been a cause of poor
countries’ bad performance. The lower ratio of trade
to GDP was therefore probably a result of lack of
development, rather than a cause of it.
The study also finds that the reliance on multilateral
lenders is unlikely to help the poorest countries.
(It could be added that this is also because such
reliance comes with greater insistence on the very
policies that have been associated with earlier lack
of growth and development.) There is another important
insight: that the much-touted positive roles of democracy
and higher education on economic growth are very difficult
to discern on the basis of the empirical evidence
alone. ''Indeed, it could be that both are primary
goods, desirable in themselves, instead of purely
instrumental goods acting as tools for higher income.
In that sense, democratization and better education
in poor countries are worthy goals, but neither seems
to be an instrument for economic development - particularly
so if other enabling conditions, like peace, are not
present.'' (page 26)
Instead, the study highlights another potentially
important reason for the slow economic growth of the
LDCs: the implications of political and social instability.
Milanovic points out that one key factor associated
with low growth is war and civil strife. The poorest
countries have lost, on average, some 40 percent of
their output through much greater frequency of war
compared with the rest of the world. According to
him, if we take the effect of wars alone, we find
that the entire relative decline of the LDCs compared
with the middle-income countries can be thus explained.
In other words, had prevalence of war among LDCs been
at the same level as elsewhere, the LDCs would have
at least kept pace with the rest of the world.
This interesting conclusion of course begs a further
question: why are there so many more wars and civil
conflicts in these LDCs? It is worth noting that most
LDCs are not poor in terms of natural resources: many
of them are sites of major reserves and ongoing extraction
of important ores and minerals, as well as producers
of agricultural commodities that require very specific
natural conditions. In fact there have been those
who have argued that it is precisely this natural
wealth that has been a curse for these countries,
attracting national and international bees to the
honey pot in the scramble for accessing or controlling
such resources. It is no secret that local conflicts
have been stoked by outside, and imperial, interests.
Aside from such considerations, however, there is
another sense in which we should not be surprised
at the higher levels of violence in LDCs. When substantial
populations are at the margin of subsistence, even
small changes in territorial access or economic policies
can have major implications for life and basic conditions
of living. So struggles over even what appear to be
relatively minor issues are fought aggressively and
bitterly, because often what is at stake is sheer
survival.
So, in a very basic sense, the extent of political
conflict and instability in particular countries also
has material foundations, even though the links are
not always so apparent. And this vicious spiral in
turn can be traced to certain kinds of neoliberal
policies characteristic of current imperialism, which
are affecting not only the world economy but especially
these particular countries.
November 07, 2005.
|