An unusual and striking
feature of the current global balance of payments situation is the huge
deficit on the current account of the world’s dominant country, the United
States, which is partly being financed with surpluses in the current and
capital account of developing countries, especially those in developing
Asia. At the end of the second quarter of 2004, the annual current account
deficit in the US balance of payments stood at $572 billion and was forecast
to touch 5.5 per cent of GDP in 2004. At around the same time, 9 developing
economies in Asia and Latin America (Brazil, China, Hong Kong, India,
Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan province of China,
and Venezuela) were recording an annual surplus of around $190 billion
on their current account.
To boot, many of these developing countries were recipients of large capital
inflows—in the form of foreign direct investment, portfolio capital and
debt—resulting in surpluses on the capital account. Together these current
and capital account surpluses were adding to their reserves, which in
turn were being invested in dollar denominated financial assets, thereby
financing in part the US deficit.
Weekly data from the Federal Reserve relating to November 3, 2004 showed
the Fed's holdings of assets for official institutions – which is a proxy
for foreign central bank holdings - rose over the previous year by $253.6
billion to $1,053 billion. This compares with a rise of $217 billion during
the whole of 2003. Needless to say, not all of these investments are from
developing countries, since Japan is a major investor. The Japanese government
spent a record $180 billion in 2003 on intervention in foreign exchange
markets and much of that money found its way into the US Treasury market.
During that period, Japan's foreign exchange reserves rose by $203.8 billion
to $673.5 billion. In the first two months of this year, those reserves
rose a further 15 per cent to $776.9 billion. While developing countries
may not be playing a similar role, their contribution is still important.
As Chart 1 shows, the current account deficit in the US has widened continuously
since the mid-1990s, resulting in an overall deficit for all advanced
economies, despite the fact that every one of them has shown surpluses
in almost all those years. On the other hand, during this period developing
countries as a group have seen a transformation of their current account
deficits into surpluses (Chart 2). While this was true initially of a
set of countries in Asia, they have since been joined by countries in
West Asia, the Commonwealth of Independent States (included by the IMF
in the developing countries and emerging markets group) and Latin America,
though not Africa and Central and Eastern Europe. However, developing
and emerging market countries outside Developing Asia have also been recording
a surplus as a group.
|
|
|
This implies that three decades of globalisation have fundamentally
transformed the international balance of payments situation. Prior to
the oil shocks, which were important triggers for the major changes in
the quantum and nature of international capital flows, the international
payments scenario reflected differences in the global economic strength
of individual nations. The scenario was one where the developed countries
recorded large surpluses, the oil-exporting developing countries much
smaller surpluses and the oil-importing developing countries were burdened
with significant deficits. The process of restoring global balance involved
adjusting growth in the oil-importing developing countries so as to tailor
their deficits to correspond to the extent to which surpluses from the
developed countries could be recycled to finance those deficits. Though
for a short period after the oil shocks of the 1970s this situation changed
with surpluses in developed countries falling, those earned by the oil
exporters rising sharply and deficits in the oil-importing developing
countries exploding, the picture returned to its pre-oil shock form by
the 1980s. Even when oil exporters were earning large surpluses, the fact
that these surpluses were being deposited within the banking system in
the developed world made the process of recycling surpluses one of transfers
from the developed to the oil-importing developing countries. The real
change was that private rather than official flows through the bilateral
and multilateral development network came to dominate capital flows.
Associated with this shift was a transformation of capitalism in the developed
countries which witnessed the rise to dominance of finance capital. To
start with, oil surpluses deposited with the international banking system
resulted in a massive increase in credit provision, both within the developed
countries and in the so-called emerging markets. Second, the breakdown
of the system of fixed exchange rates triggered by the US decision to
delink the dollar from gold, resulted in a sharp increase in foreign exchange
trading. Third, growing exposure of financial agents in domestic and international
debt markets and in foreign exchange markets resulted in the burgeoning
of derivatives that allowed financial institutions to hedge their bets
by transferring credit risk. And, finally, the liberalisation of financial
markets in developing countries aimed at exploiting the benefits of a
global financial system awash with liquidity provided an opportunity for
banks, pension funds and other financial firms to increase their investments
in developing countries in search of lucrative returns.
The long term effects of these developments are there to see. Available
figures point to galloping growth in the global operations of financial
firms. In the early 1980s, the volume of transactions of bonds and securities
between domestic and foreign residents accounted for about 10 per cent
of GDP in the US, Germany and Japan. By 1993, the figure had risen to
135 per cent for the US, 170 per cent for Germany and 80 per cent for
Japan. Much of these transactions were of bonds of relatively short maturities.
Since then, not only have these transactions increased in volume, but
a range of less traditional transactions have come to play an even more
important role. Traditional bank claims, though important, are by no means
dominant. Banks reporting to the Bank of International Settlements (BIS)
recorded foreign claims on residents of all countries at $15.7 trillion
at the end of 2003. This compares with the annual global GDP of $36400
trillion in that year.
Non-bank transactions have been far more important. In 1992, the daily
volume of foreign exchange transactions in international financial markets
stood at $820 billion, compared to the annual world merchandise exports
of $3.8 trillion or a daily value of world merchandise trade of $10.3
billion. According to the recently released Triennial Central Bank Survey
of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity, in April 2004, the
average daily turnover (adjusted for double-counting) in foreign exchange
markets stood at $1.9 trillion. With the average GDP generated globally
in a day standing at close to $100 trillion in 2003, this appears to be
a small 2 per cent relative to real economic activity across the globe.
But the sum involved is huge relative the daily value of world trade.
In 2003, the value of world merchandise exports touched $7.3 trillion,
while that of commercial services trade rose to $1.8 trillion. Thus, the
daily volume of transactions in foreign exchange markets exceeded the
annual value of trade in commercial services and was in excess of one
quarter of the annual merchandise trade.
The trade in derivatives is also large and significant. The Triennial
Survey indicates that the average daily volume of exchange traded derivatives
amounted to $4.5 trillion in 2004. In the OTC derivatives market, average
daily turnover amounted to $1.2 trillion at current exchange rates. The
OTC market section consists of “non-traditional” foreign exchange derivatives
– such as cross-currency swaps and options – and all interest rate derivatives
contracts. Thus total derivatives trading stood at $5.7 trillion a day,
which together with the $1.9 million daily turnover in foreign exchange
markets adds up to $7.6 trillion. This exceeds the annual value of global
merchandise exports in 2003.
One consequence of these developments was that the flow of capital to
developing countries, particularly the “emerging markets” among them had
nothing to do with their financing requirements. Capital in the form of
debt and equity investments began to flow into these countries, especially
those that were quick to liberalize rules relating to cross-border capital
flows and regulations governing the conversion of domestic into foreign
currency. The point to note is that these inflows did not spur substantial
productive investment in these countries. Even foreign direct investment,
defined as investment in firms where the foreign investor holds 10 per
cent or more of equity, had “portfolio” characteristics, and often took
the form of acquisitions rather than greenfield investment.
What is important from the point of view of global balances is that the
inflow of such capital imposes a deflationary environment on developing
countries, because one requirement for keeping financial investors happy
is to substantially reduce the deficit of the government or its expenditures
financed with borrowing. Financial interests are against deficit-financed
spending by the State for a number of reasons. To start with, deficit
financing is seen to increase the liquidity overhang in the system, and
therefore as being potentially inflationary. Inflation is anathema to
finance since it erodes the real value of financial assets. Second, since
government spending is “autonomous” in character, the use of debt to finance
such autonomous spending is seen as introducing into financial markets
an arbitrary player not driven by the profit motive, whose activities
can render interest rate differentials that determine financial profits
more unpredictable. Finally, if deficit spending leads to a substantial
build-up of the state’s debt and interest burden, it may intervene in
financial markets to lower interest rates with implications for financial
returns. Financial interests wanting to guard against that possibility
tend to oppose deficit spending. Given the consequent dislike of expansionary
fiscal policy on the part of financial investors, countries seeking to
attract financial flows or satisfy existing financial investors are forced
to adopt a deflationary fiscal stance, which limits their policy option.
Part of the reason why developing countries record a surplus on their
current account is the deflationary fiscal stance adopted by their governments.
Growth is curtailed through deflation so that, even with a higher import-to-GDP
ratio resulting from trade liberalisation, imports are kept at levels
that imply a trade surplus. Consider the flows that deliver current account
surpluses for developing countries? As Table 1 shows, two factors account
for these surpluses: first, the transformation of the trade deficit (goods
and services) in these countries into surpluses, and a substantial inflow
of current transfers, mainly in the form of remittances. So, unless exports
of goods and services and/or remittances are large and growing, deflation
must be the factor influencing the current account.
Table
1: The Current Account of Developing and
Emerging Market Countries ($ billion) |
|
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
2000 |
2001 |
2002 |
2003 |
Current account balance |
-86.1 |
-85.3 |
-116.3 |
-18.9 |
86.3 |
39.5 |
84.21 |
148.9 |
Balance on goods and services |
-46.6 |
-45.6 |
-66.1 |
42.2 |
147.9 |
93.5 |
128.6 |
183.4 |
Income,
net |
-83.7 |
-91.8 |
-99.5 |
-114.3 |
-188.3 |
-116.9 |
-124.5 |
-137.3 |
Current transfers, net |
44.2 |
52.1 |
49.2 |
53.2 |
56.7 |
63 |
80 |
102.7 |
|
In sum, while the inflow of remittances is reflective of one aspect
of the process of globalisation that has benefited developing countries,
the rise of trade surpluses reflect the deflation imposed by financial
flows and the financial crises they engineer in some countries. As a result,
developing countries as a group did not require capital inflows to finance
their balance of payments. But such inflows did occur, particularly in
the form of private foreign investment. Such capital inflows then either
went out as other net investment or were accumulated as reserves that
were invested in large measure in US Treasury bills. That is, private
capital flowed into developing countries to earn lucrative returns, and
this capital then flowed out as investment in low interest Treasury bills
in order to finance the US balance of trade deficit.
What is more, if a country is successful in attracting financial flows,
the consequent tendency for its currency to appreciate forces the central
bank to intervene in currency markets to purchase foreign currency and
prevent excessive appreciation. The consequent build-up of foreign currency
assets, while initially sterilized through sale of domestic assets, especially
government securities, soon reduces the monetary policy flexibility of
the central bank. Governments in Asia, especially India, faced with these
conditions are increasingly resorting to trade and capital account liberalization
to expend foreign currency and reduce the compulsion on the central bank
to keep building foreign reserves. That is, if financial liberalisation
is successful, in the first instance, in attracting capital flows, it
inevitably triggers further liberalization, including of capital outflows,
leading to an increase in financial fragility.
Thus, financial liberalisation that successfully attracts capital flows
increases vulnerability and limits the policy space of the government.
Unfortunately, the dominance of finance globally has meant that such debilitating
flows occur even when individual developing countries or developing countries
as a group have no need for such flows to finance their balance of payments
or augment their savings. The real benefit of such flows is derived by
the US government, which, being the home of the reserve currency can resort
to large scale deficit financing which it opposes in developing countries.
The resulting balance of trade and current account deficits are not a
problem because they are financed with capital flows from the rest of
the world including “emerging market” developing countries. The problem
now is that the willingness of private investors and governments to hold
more dollar denominated assets is waning. If that continues a crisis at
the metropolitan centre of global capitalism is a possibility.
November 11, 2004.
|