It
is now clear that the problems of the Greek economy
- and the eurozone - have not been and cannot be solved
by the large infusion of emergency finance from the
ECB and the IMF. The Greek government is being asked
to implement austerity measures that will cause a
major decline in incomes and employment not just now
but in the foreseeable future, and which will not
correct the existing imbalances but actually worsen
them.
The heavily-indebted poor countries (HIPCs) of Africa
could tell the Greeks a thing or two about this process.
They could tell them how the deflationary measures
that are imposed on governments cause economic activity
to go into a downward spiral that destroys existing
capacities and prospects for future growth, and pushes
large sections of the population into a fragile and
insecure material existence. They could tell them
about how it is fundamentally unsustainable, because
the downslide in GDP makes it ever harder to service
the debt, which in turn keep not only piling up but
even expanding because of the unpaid interest that
keeps getting added to the principal and then compounded,
so that the country’s debt just keeps rising even
with no fresh inflows. They could tell them how ultimately
there will be no alternative to restructuring the
debt, because the problem will only grow in magnitude
even with (and partly because of) the most stringently
applied austerity measures. They could tell them about
their own experience of several lost decades of economic
retrogression, which could have been avoided had the
debt restructuring taken place much earlier and a
different set of policies for economic recovery been
pursued.
Austerity programmes that involve cuts in public spending
will have a depressing impact on the economy and make
it much harder to "grow" out of the crisis.
In the Greek case, in the pre-crisis period the public
sector contributed around 40 per cent of GDP, so cutbacks
here are likely to have very large negative multiplier
effects, lowering economic activity and therefore
tax revenues, and perversely making it harder to reduce
the budget deficit. In the case of the US in the middle
of the crisis in 2008 and 2009, everyone (including
the IMF) agreed that it was necessary for the US government
to spend more in order to help the economy recover
and keep incomes from collapsing. That economic logic
does not disappear in the case of other countries.
This experience should point to the obvious lesson:
that there is no alternative to a major restructuring
of the Greek debt, involving a loss taken by the international
lenders who did not exercise due diligence in the
act of lending in the first place. If it does not
happen now, it will in any case have to happen at
some time in the future, after creating a great deal
of material distress in Greece.
Part of the problem is that when a country is seen
to be in payments difficulties, markets force a major
increase in the costs of servicing such debt. This
is the sense in which what is happening in Greece
today is similar to what has already happened in a
number of other countries, mostly developing ones,
because interest payments rise as the debt is seen
to be more risky. In a sense, a lot of restructuring
is already occurring in secondary markets where the
price of Greek bonds has tumbled. Such losses are
occurring for banks all the time in the private sector,
and they are usually able to handle it. The point
is to give that advantage to the Greek government,
rather than to elements outside the economy, so that
the government has more fiscal room for maneouvre
and can try to generate an economic recovery rather
than add to the slump.
The recent case of Argentina shows that such a restructuring
can occur without really damaging a country's international
position (or fundamentally harming the banks involved
or reducing their ability to lend) and can in fact
contribute to growth prospects. (Of course Argentina
had the advantage of currency depreciation, having
abandoned the currency board arrangement that tied
the peso to the US dollar in the midst of its financial
crisis in 2001.)
Why is such an obvious conclusion not even being talked
about? One likely reason is that a restructuring of
the Greek debt would involve quite a large haircut
for the German and French banks who lent extensively
during the boom, and helped to create the imbalances
that have made the Greek economy less competitive
than that of Germany, for example. This cannot be
allowed to happen because of the greater lobbying
power of finance, so the burden of adjustment is being
placed entirely on the Greek people, for several generations,
in what will clearly be an unsustainable process.
It gets worse. Other countries that are seen to have
potential problems like Greece are already moving
towards austerity measures and contractionary macroeconomic
policies that are bound to threaten the frail economic
recovery and engender or intensify the next recession.
Spain has just announced not only tightening of monetary
policies, but fiscal contraction involving cuts in
public sector pay and pensions and much else. This
is particularly remarkable because until two years
ago Spain ran a fiscal surplus (the deficit was because
of the private sector) and its recent deficits are
entirely a result of the crisis.
Ireland is already undergoing the most extreme deflationary
package involving significant decline in GDP and slashing
of public expenditure in all sorts of areas from physical
infrastructure to education. The Baltic countries,
not only Latvia which has an IMF programme but Estonia
where the pain is self-inflicted, are experiencing
dramatic declines in incomes, employment and wages
because of their severe austerity packages. In Romania
there was the recent remarkable spectacle of policemen
taking to the streets to protest against their wage
decreases. In Britain the new government is already
talking about measures to cut the deficit by slashing
spending and raising indirect taxes.
All these countries are hoping that they can export
their way out of this mess, but that is simply not
feasible as he numbers do not add up. It is close
to ridiculous to expect Greece to be able to export
its way out of trouble. It is not only that Greece
is a member of the eurozone and therefore will require
really sharp declines in price to appear competitive
relative to trading partners. It is also that most
of Greece's trade is with other countries in the eurozone.
This means that even tourism (a major foreign exchange
earner) will not generate more volume without significant
price falls. But in general, obviously every country
cannot hope to export its way out of growth, because
of the fallacy of composition, and the suppression
of domestic demand will only make it harder for other
countries to use exports to grow. In fact the European
Union as a whole will head for a major recession if
all its members try to rely on export-led growth.
So these countries - and by association, the rest
of Europe - are effectively condemning themselves
to a period of stagnation or declining incomes, with
all the economic and social problems that will generate.
How can such an illogical set of policies be taken
so seriously? The problem is that the power of finance
- in politics, in media and in determining national
and international economic policies - remains undiminished
despite its recent excesses and failures. That is
why the restructuring of public debts is not on the
agenda; that is why talk of fiscal balancing so rarely
even mentions taxes on capital, and much less on the
same financial sectors that benefited from large publicly
funded bailouts and are now holding to ransom the
hands that have fed them.
If the power of the financial class cannot be curbed
in any fundamental sense (as seems to be the case
at present) then the opportunity costs of continuing
with a currency union without a political union become
higher every day and may reach the turning point at
which countries decide it is no longer worth it. So
if the eurozone is to survive intact (without forcing
the exit of some members like Greece) there must be
much more significant fiscal federalism than has yet
been seen. The relatively stingy attempts to provide
emergency finance at interest rates that are still
high do not constitute real fiscal federalism. Basically
some institution in Europe must be able to play the
role that the US federal government currently plays
vis-à-vis Florida or California. Without such
a (fairly major) commitment, it is difficult to see
a long-term future for the current eurozone.
*
Some sections of this article were originally published
in the Guardian on 17 May 2010. http://www.guardian.co.uk/commentisfree/2010/may/17/greece-debt-restructure
May 19 , 2010.
|