Dr.
Tobin was known for applying economic theory to the
way people made decisions and for advocating the Keynesian
theory of government intervention in the economy.
Throughout his career, he battled conservative economists
like Milton Friedman, a Nobel laureate at the University
of Chicago, who disdained government intervention.
Dr. Tobin regarded his Nobel Prize as a vote of confidence
in the Keynesian theory.
Paul A. Samuelson, a professor emeritus at the Massachusetts
Institute of Technology, called Dr. Tobin "the
leading macroeconomist of our generation."A macroeconomist
studies the way an economic system performs, with
particular attention to the vagaries of budgetary
and monetary policies. Dr. Tobin also made significant
contributions to the understanding of international
financial markets, statistical methods and the study
of spending decisions by households and businesses.
The Nobel selection committee called his work a breakthrough
in analyzing the relationship of financial markets,
including those for stocks and bonds, with "real"
markets, like those for real estate, factory machinery
and consumer goods. Describing this relationship,
the committee said, had been a "classic problem
in economic research." Dr. Tobin concluded that
investors were affected by their assessments of how
risky their decisions might be and that they differed
in the amount of risk they were willing to take. He
explored the tendency to build portfolios in which
risks were balanced against more secure assets. Earlier
analyses frequently oversimplified the behavior, assuming
that investors typically sought the highest return
without regard to risk.
But Dr. Tobin's work, known as the Portfolio Selection
Theory, helped increase the understanding of an investor's
willingness to hold various assets. During times of
inflation, for instance, he found them less willing
to hold stock or cash, turning instead to bonds or
physical assets like real estate.
After he won the Nobel Prize, reporters asked him
to explain the portfolio theory. When he tried to
do so, one journalist interrupted, "Oh, no, please
explain it in lay language." So he described
the theory of diversification by saying: "You
know, don't put your eggs in one basket." Headline
writers around the world the next day created some
version of "Economist Wins Nobel for Saying,
`Don't Put Eggs in One Basket.' "
Another theory, important to investors as well as
to policy makers, was called Tobin's Q. This ratio
measures the relationship of the market value of factories
or other corporate assets to their replacement cost.
When replacement costs run high, Tobin's Q runs low,
and in those situations, companies tend to expand
by acquiring other companies instead of building plants
or buying equipment.
The theory gained prominence at the height of the
market boom in the late 1990's, when researchers noted
that the overall value of Tobin's Q in the market
looked unreasonably high relative to historical norms.
Some economists argued that such a discrepancy would
be followed by a sharp decline, which soon arrived.
When President John F. Kennedy asked him in 1961 to
join the Council of Economic Advisers, Dr. Tobin had
spent little time in government and politics, confining
himself to teaching and research first at Harvard
and, since 1950, at Yale.
"I'm afraid you've got the wrong guy, Mr. President,"
Dr. Tobin replied. "I'm an ivory tower economist."
"That's the best kind," Mr. Kennedy said.
"I'm an ivory tower president."
As things turned out, in the view of his colleagues,
Dr. Tobin brought to government the same independence
of mind and intellectual rigor that he brought to
research. He helped engineer a tax cut, not enacted
until after Mr. Kennedy's death, that many politicians
have cited as one of the most successful government
efforts to revive a halting economy.
James Tobin was born on March 5, 1918, in Champaign,
Ill., the son of Louis M. Tobin, a journalist, and
Margaret Edgerton Tobin, a social worker. As an undergraduate
at Harvard in the 1930's, he was taught economics
by Joseph A. Schumpeter, Wassily Leontief, Seymour
Harris, Alvin Hansen and other members of a department
that has become legendary.
He was attracted to economics because he felt a need
to understand the Depression and was intrigued by
the economic discussion over what should be done about
unemployment and other problems, a classic debate
between the hands-off theory of Adam Smith and the
intervention theory of John Maynard Keynes.
Dr. Tobin graduated summa cum laude in 1939 and earned
his master's degree the next year. After a wartime
interruption to serve one year in the federal government
and four years in the Navy, he returned to Harvard
to earn a Ph.D. in 1947.In the Navy, he received officer
training at Columbia University in the same class
with Cyrus R. Vance, who later became secretary of
state, and Herman Wouk, who later wrote "The
Caine Mutiny." In that novel, Dr. Tobin was the
inspiration for a midshipman named Tobit, described
by Mr. Wouk as "ahead of the field by a spacious
percentage." The appearance in the novel "was
my greatest claim to fame, until today," he joked
40 years later, on the day he won the Nobel Prize.
By that time, Tobit had become the name of a statistical
technique Dr. Tobin devised for analyzing data with
maximum or minimum values. For instance, Tobit can
accurately parse out how factors like age and income
influence individual decisions about how much to contribute
to individual retirement accounts.
In his undergraduate honors thesis, he found some
fault with Keynesian logic, though he generally gave
enthusiastic support to its principal doctrine. In
his thesis he explored an issue that would intrigue
him his entire career: Should the government intervene
in a free-market economy and, if so, to what extent?
Dr. Tobin maintained that Keynes had been right in
arguing that the economy needed help on occasion in
solving problems like severe unemployment and poverty,
but that he went further than necessary.
In an interview in 1996, Dr. Tobin described some
of his research as an effort to "fix up some
of the implausibilities in Keynesian economics and
to make more sense of it." He said, "There
has been justified criticism of the Keynesian model,
that it was too Depression-oriented." Dr. Tobin
also formalized the idea of a tax on international
transactions, which he asserted could enhance financial
stability and prevent flash currency crises, like
those that affected Southeast Asia in the late 1990's.
The "Tobin tax" found support among fellow
economists including Lawrence H. Summers, before Mr.
Summers joined the World Bank and the Treasury Department.
After the Asian crisis, many advocates for developing
countries revived the proposal.Dr. Tobin served on
the Council of Economic Advisers with Kenneth J. Arrow
and Robert M. Solow, who both went on to win Nobel
Prizes in economics.
"The Kennedy council was effective," Dr.
Tobin said, "because the president and his immediate
White House staff took academics seriously."
He served on the council under Mr. Kennedy and for
less than a year under President Lyndon B. Johnson,
when he returned to Yale. "Fifteen- hour days
and seven-day weeks were a hardship for me, my wife
and our four young children," he said. Back at
Yale, he studied the economically disadvantaged and
the inadequacies and inefficiencies of federal and
state welfare programs. During the 1972 presidential
race, Dr. Tobin helped develop for the campaign of
Senator George McGovern what was called the negative
income tax, a modest income payment to those below
the poverty line. But he said Mr. McGovern and his
staff botched its presentation in the heat of the
California primary and voters thought the proposal
was "a kooky budget-breaking handout."
A scaled-down version of such an income transfer to
the poor was later enacted into law in the first Bush
administration, but it was eliminated by President
Bill Clinton. Dr. Tobin acknowledged that some Great
Society ideas of the 60's were too optimistic about
what government could accomplish. But he said in a
1996 interview that "many of the benefit programs,
like food stamps, are credited by their opponents
as well as their supporters with having essentially
brought poverty as conservatively defined by the federal
government, down close to zero." He retired as
a faculty member in 1988 at age 70 but continued teaching
as professor emeritus. Dr. Tobin was the author of
some 500 articles and 16 books. He is survived by
his wife of 55 years, the former Elizabeth Fay Ringo;
a daughter, Margaret Ringo Segall, of New York; three
sons, Louis Michael, of Madison, Wis.; Hugh Ringo,
of Seattle; and Roger Gill, of Belmont, Mass.; a brother,
Roger Gill, of Venice, Fla.; and three grandchildren.
March 13, 2002.
[Source: New York Times, March
13, 2002]
|