One
crucial parameter for computing the sufficiency of
capitalisation is the average risk weight (RW) applied
to bank assets. Banks with the same value of capital
and total assets but different RWs may end in red
or black for capital sufficiency. If the RWs were
to reflect the true degree of bank risk that would
be what prudential regulation was designed for. If,
on the contrary, the regulatory RWs were distorted
by inappropriate rules and heterogeneous supervisory
practices, the result would be a complete regulatory
failure. After the recent crises, the official authorities
had to recognise that many rules were distorting the
RWs (especially those relating to the trading book)
and that the discretion attributed to national supervisors
was in many cases responsible for the light touch
that started or deepened the crisis.
Regarding the rules, two European Directives (CRD
II and CRD III) have addressed the problem of the
low risk weight for the trading book and securitisation,
potentially tripling the value of the RW applied to
such activities. The objective of the new calibration
is to re-equilibrate the RWs of different parts of
the portfolio, abolishing the incentives favouring
the trading book. Regarding discretion, three new
European supervisory authorities have been created
with the precise objective of homogenising supervisory
practices across the EU Member Countries.
In the banking sphere, one of the first initiatives
taken by the new European Banking Authority (EBA)
has been to promote a new stress test for 91 EU banks,
adopting a common and supposedly stringent methodology.
The recent publication of the results of the test
offers much food for thought. This brief note only
focuses on the RWs in order to suggest that the two
above mentioned reforms are not producing the desired
results.
In short, the European Banking Authority has substantially
accepted the projected RWs that were transmitted by
the banks, supposedly with the seal of their national
supervisory authorities, for the years 2011 and 2012
under the two baseline and adverse scenarios. Starting
from January 2011, these coefficients should also
incorporate by the beginning of 2012 all of the RWs'
increases dictated by the two above mentioned Directives.
It is worth noting is that if the banks were not to
send their calculations on their perspective RWs for
market risks, the EBA would have applied a floor for
their increase with multipliers of 1.1 and 1.4 for
banks utilising the standardised or IEB approach respectively.
Not much, if we think that these multipliers only
apply to market risks.
The RWs for 2011 and 2012 shown in the Tables 1 and
2 are computed dividing the amount of the risk weighted
assets by the level of total assets. Since both quantities
are the result of a complex set of evaluations, including
the opposite effects due to the higher risks included
in the baseline scenario and some write-offs, of which
no detailed data are given, a very neat evaluation
is difficult. However, we hardly observe for the following
two years a significant general increase of the average
RWs with respect to 2010, even in a stressed scenario.
This result may be due to the fact that although the
RW for market risk increases substantially, its very
low starting level renders the overall effect almost
negligible.
Deutsche Bank is a good example. Although its risk
weighted assets for market risk as a percentage of
total risk weighted assets almost triple, going from
7% in 2010 to 20% in 2012, the average RW only increase
of 25.5%. Starting with the lowest average RW, Deutsche
ends in the same relative position. Even if Deutsche
were punished with a 9.5% of Tier 1 capital requirement
for being a Global SIFI, it could go on in a 2012
stressed scenario with a maximum leverage of 46, well
above the 33 that the Basel Committee generously suggested
as a tentative cap. Since Deutsche accounts for the
more significant increase from among the sample, it
seems that we cannot count on the new rules on RWs
to decrease leverage and improve resilience.
Table
1: RWs of the EU banks among the
first World 20 for total assets |
00 |
Baseline
scenario |
2012
Max Leverage
for T1/RWA=9.5%*
|
|
00 |
2010 |
2011 |
2012 |
DEUTSCHE BANK AG |
DE |
0.18 |
0.22 |
0.23 |
46 |
BARCLAYS plc |
GB |
0.27 |
0.31 |
0.31 |
34 |
BNP PARIBAS |
FR |
0.30 |
0.33 |
0.34 |
31 |
SOCIETE GENERALE |
FR |
0.33 |
0.37 |
0.37 |
28 |
CREDIT AGRICOLE |
FR |
0.37 |
0.37 |
0.37 |
28 |
ROYAL BANK OF SCOTLAND
GROUP plc |
GB |
0.45 |
0.46 |
0.45 |
23 |
HSBC HOLDINGS plc |
GB |
0.46 |
0.51 |
0.51 |
21 |
LLOYDS BANKING GROUP
plc |
GB |
0.47 |
0.50 |
0.50 |
21 |
BANCO SANTANDER S.A. |
ES |
0.49 |
0.50 |
0.51 |
21 |
Average |
0.37 |
0.40 |
0.40 |
00 |
Normalised
SD |
0.27 |
0.24 |
0.24 |
00 |
* To
take into account the systemic relevance of these
banks I have added a 1% capital
buffer with respect to
the 8.5% minimum of Basel 3.
Source: my calculations on data from
EBA, 2011 EU-wide stress test disclosure
template.xls.
|
Table
2 - RWs: country averages without the
largest banks included in Table 1* |
00 |
Baseline
scenario |
2012
Max Leverage
for T1/RWA=8.5%
|
00
|
2010 |
2011 |
2012 |
DE |
0.27 |
0.27 |
0.27 |
39 |
NL |
0.32 |
0.32 |
0.32 |
33 |
BE |
0.33 |
0.36 |
0.38 |
28 |
FR |
0.41 |
0.42 |
0.44 |
24 |
SE |
0.42 |
0.42 |
0.42 |
25 |
DK |
0.43 |
0.43 |
0.43 |
24 |
IE |
0.54 |
0.54 |
0.54 |
19 |
GR |
0.55 |
0.55 |
0.55 |
19 |
IT |
0.58 |
0.58 |
0.58 |
18 |
ES |
0.63 |
0.63 |
0.63 |
17 |
AT |
0.64 |
0.67 |
0.67 |
16 |
PT |
0.67 |
0.67 |
0.67 |
16 |
Average |
0.48 |
0.49 |
0.49 |
00 |
Normalised
SD |
0.27 |
0.27 |
0.26 |
00 |
* The
Table does not include UK since the four British
banks of the sample are among
the 20 world largest
of Table 1.
Source: my calculations on data from
EBA, 2011 EU-wide stress test disclosure
template.xls
|
Let's then consider the re-balancing issue. While
Table 1 shows the data for the banks of the sample
that are among the 20 world largest, Table 2 refers
to the country averages of the rest of the sample.
We may easily suppose that the largest banks generally
operate with higher market risks. A large difference
in RWs exists between the largest banks and the average
of the other sample, and that the gap is going to
persist. No re-balancing is, then, is going to come
from the new rules. If they were wrong at the onset
of the crisis, they remain firmly so.
The heterogeneity in national supervisory practices
too is still alive and well. First, the two tables,
which list banks and country averages with RW in increasing
order, present a good correspondence at country level.
Second, the variability of the two samples is much
the same. The data thus suggest that at least a large
part of the variability of RWs is due to national
factors, supervisory ones in the first place. As in
the previous cases, the old distortions are not going
to disappear.
It is easy to understand how different should have
been the results of the stress test if the re-balancing
toward the higher levels of RW were homogeneously
in place. The German banks, among others, have much
to celebrate.
July
25, 2011.
|