Christine
Lagarde has been busy this June. The French Foreign
Minister and European Union candidate for the top
job at the International Monetary Fund has been visiting
the capitals of ''important'' emerging countries -
Brazil, India, China, Russia – to drum up support
for her candidacy. For their part, governments in
these and other developing countries, after an initial
show of being united in irritation at the blatant
attempts by Europe to keep control over this slot,
have been too wary of each other to agree on a common
candidate, at least thus far. The only declared candidate
from a developing country, Agustin Caarstens from
Mexico, has not yet received explicit support from
any other country.
In any case, because voting rights at the IMF have
barely changed despite the shifts in the global economy
over the past six decades, the developing countries
on their own would simply not have enough votes to
put in a candidate of their choice. Things might be
different if they can persuade the United States to
back a common candidate of their own, but that is
unlikely, especially if the candidate in question
does not have a record that makes him or her more
than acceptable to the Obama administration.
So it seems that the IMF will once again be headed
by someone from Europe. This has been the convention
based on an unwritten ''gentlemen's agreement'' at
the Bretton Woods conference in 1944, when the US
and the European powers agreed to share the top jobs
at the IMF and the World Bank among themselves, with
the World Bank's chief always coming from the US.
This convention emerged and was entrenched over a
period when it was also quite clear that these two
broad groupings were in dominant control of the global
economy.
That is much less clear today, and certainly the course
of the medium term future of the world economy is
unlikely to be scripted only by these two players.
Before the emergency exit of Dominique Strauss-Kahn
had rendered the choice of the next head of the IMF
an urgent matter, it was common to hear voices even
from the developed countries suggesting that the next
person to be in charge could and should be someone
from the developing world.
Of course it would be nice to see some diversity in
these powerful positions: not just of region, but
gender and so on. There are those that point out that
this has only symbolic value, as the content of both
IMF policies and management style need not change
according to the origin, gender or background of the
head. After all, the experience at the World Trade
Organisation shows that regional background of the
head need not change very much: thus Supachai from
Thailand as Secretary General made little appreciable
difference to the functioning of the organisation.
But even symbols matter. And in any case, the fierce
and almost immediate insistence on the part of the
Europeans that the IMF chief must come from their
own region suggests that there may be more to it than
pure symbolism.
In fact, the reason for this is not just because of
the perceived desire of European governments to retain
some semblance of control over global institutions.
It is also because the major immediate work of the
IMF is mainly in Europe, with several European economies
currently involved in rescue packages with the IMF,
and others unhappily waiting in the queue. Greece
and Ireland are already receiving IMF packages that
are seen as lifelines to continued (if flickering)
acceptance by the financial markets for their government
bond issues; Portugal has just signed an agreement;
Poland, Latvia and Hungary have been getting IMF support
for a while now; and there is no surety that other
''peripheral'' European economies will not have to
join in.
The argument in Europe is that since European countries
are likely to be involved in bailout packages in the
immediate future, it is especially important to have
a European head the Fund. This is an extraordinary
(but typical) display of double standards, because
this was precisely the argument earlier used (including
by Europeans) against having a person from the developing
world head the institution. It was felt that debtor
countries could not and should not provide the leadership
of the IMF because of possible conflicts of interest.
Obviously, such logic no longer applies when the boot
is on the other foot.
But in fact, the Europeans pushing for a quick choice
of one of their own to head the IMF may actually be
shooting themselves in the foot, not just geopolitically
but even as far as their own economic recovery is
concerned. The way that the recent IMF bailouts have
been organised, in co-operation with the European
Union, has actually intensified the economic recession
in these countries and prolonged the process without
providing a clear path to resolution.
This is because, despite much explicit protestation
to the contrary, the IMF even under Strauss-Kahn did
not change its basic approach and orientation. It
continued to push procyclical policies on countries
experiencing balance of payments difficulties when
they approached it for funds, even as it was applauding
the US government for undertaking countercyclical
policies in 2009. Draconian austerity packages have
been imposed on countries that are already struggling
with asset deflation and collapses in private economic
activity. Unsurprisingly, this has been associated
with worsening conditions – not just for the poor,
for wage workers, for the unemployed and for citizens
facing cuts in social services – but also for the
macroeconomy. The reductions in public spending have
come at a time when private spending is already on
the decline, and so the negative multiplier effects
have actually fed into each other and created a downward
spiral.
This obviously makes public debt even more difficult
to manage, because as GDP falls, the public debt to
GDP ratio rises! As that ratio increases, financial
agents further batter the country's government in
bond markets, and so the whole crazy negative process
continues. Many developing countries that have been
forced to take this medicine know this process only
too well. They also know that some amount of debt
restructuring (which involves a write-down of the
value of the external debt) is not just desirable
but inevitable, and requires only a small amount of
sharing of the severe economic pain that the citizens
are forced to undergo. But at least many of these
countries have been able to come out of this crisis
eventually by devaluing their currency – an option
which the troubled countries in the eurozone have
so far rejected.
In fact, with all this experience of continually getting
it wrong in so many countries over so many decades,
you would have thought that the IMF would have learned
something from its own mistakes. By now it should
surely know that countercyclical policies involving
more public expenditure are more effective than fiscal
austerity in pulling countries out of recession. It
should also have been the first to recognise that
the current debt situation of many ''peripheral''
European economies is simply unsustainable. So, instead
of falling in line with and even accentuating the
European Union's insistence that the entire burden
of adjustment must be borne by the deficit countries,
it should have pushed for a debt restructuring that
forced banks to take a haircut as a step towards a
more sustainable trajectory.
What is even more bizarre is that the IMF is now advocating
fiscal austerity for everyone, not just the countries
in deficit facing problems with bond markets! In addition
to forcing Ireland, Greece and Portugal to embark
on painful and counterproductive austerity measures,
it is advocating fiscal restraint in the US and even
in Germany. It has recently lauded the austerity measures
in the United Kingdom, which look certain to prolong
the recession in that country and to keep unemployment
high, and which even the OECD recently criticized
as being excessive.
Why would the IMF persist in pushing such blatantly
counterproductive strategies? The only constituency
that they clearly favour is finance, in these cases
the European (mostly German, French, British and Dutch)
banks that have lent heavily to the economies in distress.
So it is hard not to see that class interests - and
the interests of the financial class in particular
- have determined this set of policies, rather than
national interests per se.
This means a change of guard at the IMF would help
only if it involved a significant change in its approach
to economic policies. Someone like Christine Lagarde
is likely to pursue even more enthusiastically these
same self-defeating and economically damaging measures.
But then so are several of the possible candidates
from developing countries. Indeed, probably the only
reason that they are even considered to be ''credible''
candidates is because international finance trusts
them to deliver much of the same.
All this is unlikely to change unless there is a broader
political consensus around the world in favour of
a real transformation in economic policies, away from
privileging finance towards controlling it and being
more concerned with the welfare of citizens and society
in general. If the recent protests across Europe are
any indication, such political change may well be
on its way in Europe.
Note: This article was originally
published in The Frontline, Volume 28 Issue 13: June
18-July 01, 2011.
July
5, 2011.
|