A well-known philosophy of Francis
Bacon is his enumeration of what he calls "idols" by which is
meant bad habits of the mind that cause people to err. One of these is
the "idols of the market-place". Though I use it in a different
sense, some respondents to my article have demonstrated that they have
difficulty escaping from what is generally called TINA (there is no alternative)
mindset. I am not surprised by the nature of the response to my article
from young economics graduates, as nothing other than neo-liberal economics
is taught in the classrooms. I will confine myself here to substantial
arguments and have no intention to deal with specific criticisms though
they are valid within limits. It will suffice to say that ‘distant’ does
not mean that I have been out of the discipline.
Let me begin with the opening two paragraphs of a recently published book
by a Harvard University professor.
"On a visit to a small Latin American country a few years back, my
colleagues and I paid a courtesy visit to the minister of finance. The
minister had prepared a detailed PowerPoint presentation on his economy's
recent progress and listed all the reforms that they had undertaken. Trade
barriers had been removed, price controls had been lifted, and all public
enterprises had been privatized. Fiscal policy was tight, public debt
levels low, and inflation non-existent. Labor markets were as flexible
as they come. There were no exchange or capital controls, and the economy
was open to foreign investments of all kind. 'We have done all the first
generation reforms, all the second generation reforms, and are now embarking
on third generation reforms' he said proudly.
Indeed the country and its finance minister had been excellent students
of the teaching on development policy emanating from international financial
institutions and North American academics. And if there were justice in
the world in matters of this kind, the country in question would have
been handsomely rewarded with rapid growth, poverty reduction. Alas not
so! The economy was scarcely growing, private investment remained depressed,
and largely as a consequence, poverty and inequality were on the rise.
What had gone wrong?” (Dani Rodrik, One Economics Many Recipes: Globalization,
Institutions and Economic Growth, Princeton University Press, 2007, p.
1)
Many students of economics were forced to accept free and unprotected
trade, minimum state intervention, and uncontrolled foreign investment
as fundamental conditions of economic development. They were also made
to believe that today’s developed countries had achieved their success
in economic development through free and unprotected trade, and minimum
state intervention. If we consider history as the laboratory of economics,
it gives ample evidence that these economic nostrums are absolutely incorrect.
In this article, I will deal with the argument of free trade leaving other
issues like government intervention and foreign investment for a separate
article. Let me cite examples from Great Britain and the USA.
Great Britain: At the beginning of the 19th
century, the average tariff rate on manufactures was 50 per cent-high
by almost any comparative standard. It reduced its tariff on manufactures
after it reached world economic pre-eminence.
USA: According to the World Bank estimates,
the average US tariff on manufactures was 40 per cent in 1820. It was
around 30 per cent for most of the 1870 to 1910 period.
Though it was normally believed that trade protection was higher in Germany
and France than it was in Britain and the US, facts dispute it. Responding
to my article, AJ writes: "People who
oppose free trade automatically support inefficient domestic producers
(local entrepreneurs who get fat on the poor consumers)." Let me
narrate a story.
"Once upon a time, the leading car maker of a developing country
exported its first passenger car to the US. Up to that day, the little
company had only shoddy products. The car was nothing too sophisticated.
But it was a big moment for the country and its exporters felt proud.
Unfortunately, the product failed. The car had to be withdrawn from the
US market. This disaster led to a major debate among the country’s citizens.
Many argued that the company should have stuck to its original business
of making simple textile machinery. If the company could not make good
cars after 25 years of trying, there was no future for it. The government
had given the car maker every opportunity to succeed. It had ensured high
profits for it at home through high tariffs and draconian controls on
foreign investment in the car industry. Fewer than ten years ago, it even
gave public money to save the company from imminent bankruptcy. So the
critic argued, foreign cars should now be let in freely and foreign car
makers, who had been kicked out 20 years before, allowed to set up shop
again.
Others disagreed. They argued that no country had got anywhere without
developing 'serious' industries like automobile production. They just
needed more time to make cars that appealed to everyone.
The year was 1958 and the country was, in fact, Japan. The company was
Toyota." (Ha-Joon Chang, Bad Samaritans: The Myth of Free Trade and
the Secret of Capitalism, Bloomsbury Press, 2008, p. 19)
Ricardo-HOS Model
Not only does the neo-classical orthodoxy not sit very well with historical
experience in developed countries, it is theoretically flawed. The Ricardian
principle and its later modifications are essentially wrong as they are
based on static assumption in explaining potentially dynamic situations.
I will prove this point by using a simple example. Figure 1 presents a
simple comparative advantage model by using Ricardian two-country trade
relations.
Figure 1
|
Tea |
Cloth |
Domestic Barter Rate |
Sri Lanka |
80 |
90 |
1 tea = 0.8 cloth |
England |
120 |
100 |
1 tea = 1.2 cloth |
In this example, Sri Lanka has an absolute advantage in producing both
tea and cloth over England. According to the Ricardian principle, this
does not prevent the two countries from entering into trading transactions
because Sri Lanka has a comparative advantage in producing tea while England
possesses comparative advantage in producing cloth. So, both countries
will be benefited if Sri Lanka specializes in production of tea while
England specializes in production of cloth. But the story does not end
there. Since production of cloth is characterized by increasing returns,
technological growth and synergy and production of tea is subject to decreasing
returns, in the process, England will become rich and developed and Sri
Lanka will remain poor and underdeveloped.
Neo-liberal orthodoxy suggests that a country should specialize in production
in which it has comparative advantage determined by its factor endowment.
Hence, when the South Korean government planned POSCO (Pohang Iron and
Steel Company) in the late 1960s, the World Bank refused to finance it
on the grounds that the project was not viable. Since South Korea's traditional
exports consisted of fish, cheap apparel, wigs and plywood and it did
not possess iron ore and coking coal, the decision appeared insensible.
But, dynamic changes can transform comparative disadvantage into comparative
advantage. Today, POSCO (now privatized) has become one of the most efficient
steel makers in the world and the third largest. What would have happened
had South Korea allowed the so-called market logic to operate? Paul Krugman
has observed that in the US a very few actually follow the standard neo-liberal
trade theory model. He writes: "[T]he view of trade as a quasi-military
competition is the conventional wisdom among policy makers, business leaders,
and influential intellectuals… It is not just that economics has lost
control of the discourse; the kinds of ideas that are offered in a standard
economics textbook do not enter into that discourse at all" (except
in the global south).
This brings us to an issue of great importance: Is the state inherently
inefficient, bad and wasteful? Should the role of the state be limited
to maintenance of law and order, provision of legal and property rights,
and provision of security for its citizens? As suggested earlier, I leave
this issue for a separate article.
We may specify four developmental models, namely, (1) free market neo-liberal
orthodox model; (2) development state model under authoritarian rule;
(3) social-democratic model; and (4) state command centrally planned model.
These are broad categories. In the real world many combinations and hybridities
exist. In my view, the development experience in the last 250 years shows
that model 1 (except in case of Hong Kong and Chile under Pinochet) and
Model 4 (whatever the initial successes) failed to make development sustainable
in the under-developed countries’ context. What Sri Lanka tried in the
last three decades (1977-2008) has been much closer to the Chilean model
but with limited and formal democracy and without complete reversal of
the pre-1977 welfare policies. Model 2 cannot work in countries like India
and Sri Lanka with their long democratic tradition (whatever the democratic
deficit and limitations). If we operate within broad categories, there
is an alternative, and the alternative is some form of social democracy,
and that alternative can be legitimized not only by pure economic reasoning
but by other reasoning as well.
July 11, 2008.
* The writer teaches political economy at the University of Peradeniya.
E-mail: sumane_l@yahoo.com
|