The
collapse of the energy trader Enron on December 2—the
largest bankruptcy in US corporate history—has
resulted in a series of increasingly critical comments
both in the American and international press.
While detailing the extent of the collapse and the
corrupt and possibly criminal activity that played
such a crucial role in the functioning of Enron, sometimes
in quite strident terms, all of this commentary serves
an essential political purpose. It seeks to stop investigation
at the very point where it must go deeper.
The decisive question which is not raised, let alone
answered, is what are the driving forces within the
economy that have led to the situation where corruption
and even criminal activity have come to play such
a central role. Enron was not only the seventh largest
US corporation, it was regarded as a "market
leader".
The rightwing Washington Post commentator George Will,
in an article published in the January 22 edition
of the Australian Financial Review, claims that problems
revealed by Enron’s collapse are "rooted
in recent changes in US legal, financial and accounting
professions," which had their origins in an "epidemic
of aggressiveness in the 1980s, when all three professions
began to think of themselves as ‘can do’
people—‘problem solvers’ who ‘think
outside the box."
The result of this mentality and the increasing use
of stock options, he maintains, was a "hyper-aggressive
management cadre continually trying to impress analysts
with ambitious targets for growth in stock values.
When the targets were met, the analysts raised the
bar, and sometimes the ever-higher expectations could
not be met without financial and accounting practices
that were the equivalent of steroids."
Will concludes that the primary cause of Enron’s
"risky behavior" was the "growing arrogance
of executives who became confident that no-one was
looking over their shoulders, watching—and understanding—what
they were doing."
But all the essential questions remain unanswered.
For instance, what is to account for the changes in
accounting and financial practices in the 1980s and
how did they come to dominate? Why the concentration
on share valuations and ever-increasing expectations?
And why the abandonment of regulatory procedures that
had been established over decades? None of these questions
is even touched on.
In a comment published on January 15, New York Times
columnist Paul Krugman dubbed the Enron affair "crony
capitalism, US style" and pointed out that the
"real story is much bigger" than one company.
Three days later, in a comment titled "A System
Corrupted", he further elaborated.
"The Enron debacle," he wrote, "is
not just the story of a company that failed; it is
the story of a system that failed. And the system
didn’t fail through carelessness or laziness;
it was corrupted."
According to Krugman, the Enron affair has revealed
that the institutions governing the capitalist economy,
including modern accounting rules, independent auditors,
securities and financial market regulation, and the
prohibitions against insider trading have been corrupted.
"The truth is that key institutions that underpin
our economic system have been corrupted. The only
question that remains is how far and how high the
corruption extends."
But for all his denunciations of "the system,"
Krugman leaves the analysis at the point where it
should really begin. His articles amount to a series
of descriptions which, in the end, explain nothing.
The corruption of Enron is explained by the corruption
of the system which was supposed to regulate and control
it. So in the end, the existence of corruption is
explained by ... corruption, the source of which is
never probed.
Postwar economic changes
The significance and implications of the Enron collapse
can only be grasped by examining it within the context
of the historical development of the capitalist economy,
in particular the post-World War II period.
Taken as a whole this epoch falls broadly into two
parts. Expanding accumulation of capital, the growth
of profits, and a general increase in living standards
in the major capitalist countries marks the period
from 1945 to 1973. In the last 25 years, starting
with the global recession of 1974-75, profit rates
are estimated to be around half what they were in
the earlier period, living standards have remained
stagnant or even declined and unemployment has been
higher.
While the business cycle—boom, downswing, recession
and upswing—has operated in both periods, its
characteristics have been markedly different. As Leon
Trotsky explained, the business cycle is to capitalism
what breathing is to a living human being. Breathing
continues from the moment of birth until death, but
its character changes and these changes provide an
indication of the health of the body.
Likewise, the business cycle has accompanied capitalism
from its birth and will continue for as long as the
system exists. Like breathing, it provides an indication
of general economic health.
Viewed from this standpoint, the past decade of economic
expansion in the US—the period which saw the
rise of Enron and other so-called "new economy"
companies—forms a marked contrast with earlier
cycles. The 1990s upswing and boom constitute the
longest period of growth in the history of American
capitalism. But overall the average annual growth
rate in the US economy in this period was only 3.1
percent. This fell short of the rate in the 1970s,
was only marginally above the growth in the 1980s—acknowledged
as a decade of considerable economic problems—and
was well below the growth rates of 4 percent plus
for the US economy in the 1950s and 1960s.
The contrast becomes even more apparent if we consider
the character of economic life in the 1990s with that
of the 1950s and 1960s. The past period, especially
the last decade, has been characterised by vast changes
in the processes of production, associated with the
computer chip, whereas the earlier period is characterised
by relative stability in production processes. Yet
the growth rate of the earlier period far exceeds
that of the past decade. In other words, a great deal
more economic activity is required to produce the
same results as previously. That is, the "breathing"
of the capitalist system has become rather laboured.
This points to changes at the very heart of the process
of capitalist production. Under this system, production
is not carried out to increase social wealth or meet
social needs, but to expand capital through the accumulation
of profit. This process takes place from capitalism’s
birth until its death. The crucial issue, which determines
its state of health in any period, is the rate at
which this accumulation occurs. That is, in the final
analysis, the "breathing" of the capitalist
economy, the business cycle, expresses the rate at
which this accumulation, indicated by the rate of
profit, is taking place.
In his analysis of the capitalist economy, Marx demonstrated
that there was an inherent tendency for this rate
of capital accumulation, measured by the rate of profit,
to decline. This tendency arises from the very structure
of the capitalist economy itself. While the sole source
of profit is the surplus value extracted from living
labour in the processes of production, the outlay
on this labour power forms an ever-smaller proportion
of the total capital laid out in the production process.
In other words, a relatively smaller amount of living
labour has to expand an ever-larger mass of capital.
When the rate of increase in the surplus value extracted
from this labour fails to keep pace with the expansion
of capital, the rate of profit begins to fall. This
decline in the rate of profit sets in motion other
processes within the capitalist economy aimed at trying
to overcome it—processes which have been increasingly
apparent over the past two decades.
"If the rate of profit falls," Marx wrote,
"there follows, on the one hand, an exertion
of capital in order that the individual capitalists,
through improved methods, etc., may depress the value
of their individual commodity below the social average
value and thereby realise an extra profit at the prevailing
market-price. On the other hand, there appears swindling
and a general promotion of swindling by recourse to
frenzied ventures with new methods of production,
new investments of capital, new adventures, all for
the sake of securing a shred of extra profit which
is independent of the general average and rises above
it" [Capital, Volume III, Marx, pp. 253-254].
Increases in productivity
Throughout its history, capitalism has continually
developed the productivity of labour through new methods
of production, based on new technologies. However,
this increase in the productivity of labour has a
contradictory impact on the rate of profit. To the
extent that increased labour productivity drives labour
out of the process of production it tends to lessen
the mass of surplus value and depress the profit rate.
However, to the extent that increased labour productivity
enables increased extraction of surplus value from
those workers remaining in the production process,
it tends to increase the mass of surplus value, leading
to expanded capital accumulation.
This means that a development of labour productivity
throughout the economy will tend to provide an expansion
in the rate of profit to the extent that the latter
tendency predominates over the former. If this takes
place the capitalist economy will undergo an expansion
and the "breathing" becomes easier.
That was certainly the case for the three decades
following World War II. The vast increases in labour
productivity resulting from the extension of assembly-line
methods of production throughout the major capitalist
countries brought about increases in the rate of profit
and a general expansion of accumulation. However,
from the mid-1970s onwards, profits began to turn
down.
Over the past quarter century, capital has responded
in the manner indicated by Marx. On the one hand there
has been a frantic drive to increase the productivity
of labour, while on the other there has been a growth
of speculative attempts to overcome falling profits
through financial means.
There is no denying that technological changes have
brought about vast increases in the productivity of
labour. For example, US Steel employed 120,000 people
in 1980. A decade later its workforce had dropped
to 20,000 yet output was only slightly lower. During
the 1980s, the steelmaking area of Sheffield saw the
destruction of tens of thousands of jobs. Yet steel
output from that region is as high as any time in
the past. In the same decade the General Electric
Company cut its workforce by over 40 percent, yet
its sales tripled.
Many examples from other industries could be produced
which make clear that there have been significant
increases in labour productivity. But what is also
clear is that this rise in productivity has resulted
in little, if any, increase in the average rate of
profit.
According to the US economist Fred Moseley, the rate
of profit fell from 22 percent in the late 1940s to
12 percent in the mid-1970s—a decline of almost
50 percent. Vast changes in the US economy over the
next two decades—including the driving down
of real wage levels—have brought about an increase.
But despite these efforts, the rate of profit in the
mid-1990s had only increased from 12 to 16 percent.
That is, it had only recovered about 40 percent of
its earlier decline and was still 30 percent below
its previous peak.
Many economic processes testify to the continuous
downward pressure on profit rates in all sections
of industry including: the existence of overcapacity
in many key industries, the intense competition in
all sectors of the economy and the billion dollar
mergers of the recent period as corporations seek
to cut costs and eliminate competition.
The failure to overcome the downward pressure on the
rate of profit in the process of production has led
to increased attempts to circumvent it by financial
means. According to British economist Harry Shutt,
since the start of the 1980s an increasing proportion
of the return on investments has resulted from capital
gains (an appreciation in the market value of the
financial asset) rather than from earnings. He has
estimated that some 75 percent of total returns in
Britain and the US came from this source in the period
from 1979 as compared with a rate of well under 50
percent in the period 1900-79.
"This clearly suggests," he concluded, "that
the rise in value has been driven more by the increasing
flow of funds into the market and speculation that
prices will continue to be pushed upwards ... than
by the actual income stream produced by the securities"
[The Trouble with Capitalism, Harry Shutt, p. 124].
Financial regulation scrapped
This points to a crucial feature of the political
economy of the recent period. Under conditions where
profits increasingly take the form of gains from financial
transactions, the markets require an ever-greater
inflow of funds—a veritable “wall of money”—to
sustain them. Those who purchase financial assets
(for example shares) at prices which would have previously
been dismissed as “irrational” are able
to do so provided more money comes into the market
to push prices still higher and bring them a capital
gain.
This need for increased inflows of money is one of
the reasons why the past decade has seen the dismantling
of previous systems of regulation—the scrapping
of the Glass-Steagall Act in 1999 in the US which
prevented banks from engaging in investment and commercial
activities is a case in point—and the hostility
to the establishment of new regimes of control. The
opposition to regulation stems from the fact that
ultimately it represents a constriction on the flow
of money needed to sustain the addiction of financial
markets.
The need of financial markets for an expanding flow
of funds is one of the driving forces behind the changes
to the pension system in the US and elsewhere. The
basis of these changes has been to tie funds directly
into the financial markets, meaning that, as in the
case of Enron, workers face the prospect of having
their entire savings and future income wiped out overnight.
The extent of these changes is highlighted by figures
compiled by the OECD—the 30-member group of
the major capitalist economies. It found that the
value of financial assets held by investor institutions
in the member states (consisting of pension funds
and insurance companies) rose by $9,800 billion between
1990 and 1995—an annual average increase equivalent
to 10 percent of GDP. [See The Trouble with Capitalism,
Harry Shutt, pp. 110-111.]
It is this increased flow of funds in the 1990s which
generated so many of the illusions in the so-called
“new economy”—illusions that are
sustained by the very functioning of capitalism itself.
One of the sources of mystification within the capitalist
system is that, viewed from the standpoint of the
market, all sections of capital appear to be the same.
It appears that a certain mass of money generates
a profit out of its very nature as money.
But there are fundamental differences between the
forms of capital. While they generate a return, financial
assets are not themselves productive capital engaged
in the actual extraction of surplus value from the
working class. They are only titles to property, that
is, claims upon the income generated by other sections
of capital. This means that while it is possible for
corporations to overcome the pressure on profit rates
through activities in the financial market, there
are definite limits to this process, set by the fact
that the ultimate source of all forms of revenue to
capital is the surplus value extracted from the working
class.
The approach towards these limits gives rise to significant
changes in the physiognomy of the capitalist economy.
Forced to turn to operations in financial markets
to secure profits, all sections of capital become
increasingly dependent on their ability to attract
new money. Keynes once likened the financial markets
to a beauty quest. In such a contest, the participants
need to dress themselves up, hide their blemishes
and conceal damaging information from the judges.
So it is in financial markets. But unlike the beauty
contest, which is a once-for-all event, judgment in
the market is a never-ending process. In the struggle
for funds, bad news, leading to a fall in share values,
can spell disaster. Under conditions where each corporation
must not only make a profit but must be seen to do
better than “market expectations”, the
pressure to cover up the real situation becomes intolerable.
Thus potentially damaging news, such as the increase
in debt, as in the case of Enron, must be concealed,
accounting must be carried out to inflate sales and
profits and shift bad news “off balance sheet”.
Employees’ pension and 401(k) funds must be
locked in to prevent a fall in share values. Deceit
and falsification become endemic.
Speaking to NBC’s “Meet the Press”
current affairs program last Sunday, Joseph Berardino,
the head of accounting giant Arthur Andersen, the
Enron auditors, pointed to the extent of these methods.
“To my knowledge,” he said, “there
was nothing that we’ve found out that was illegal.”
In other words, the financial and accounting practices
at Enron were regarded as the norm.
In the coming weeks and months there will be growing
calls for controls and regulation, for a tightening
of accounting practices so that something like Enron
can never happen again ... just as there have been
such calls after previous financial disasters.
A comment in the January 28 edition of the Newsweek
magazine sets the tone. “The key to the Enron
mess,” it claims, “is that the company
was allowed to give misleading financial information
to the world for years. Those fictional figures, showing
nicely rising profits, enabled Enron to become the
nation’s seventh largest company, with $100
billion of annual revenues. Once accurate numbers
started coming out in October, thanks to pressure
from stockholders, lenders and the previously quiescent
SEC, Enron was bankrupt in six weeks. The bottom line:
we have to change the rules to make companies deathly
afraid of producing dishonest numbers, as we have
to make accountants mortally afraid of certifying
them. Anything else is window dressing.”
Such comments are aimed at trying to assuage public
anger on the one hand and blocking an in-depth examination
of the underlying causes of the collapse on the other.
The Enron debacle was not the product of the failure
of accounting methods but was deeply rooted in structural
changes in the capitalist economy itself.
It was not that Kenneth Lay and his fellow Enron executives
started out with a plan to establish a corrupt and
very possibly criminal enterprise. Rather, it was
the entire economic environment in which they operated,
conditioned by the deep-going crisis of the profit-system
itself, which dictated their resort to ever more dubious
practices. Moreover, the changes in accounting procedures,
the abandonment of audit standards, the development
of conflicts of interest etc., which cleared the way
for the Enron management, were themselves the outcome
of this environment. The accounting firms responsible
for audit and financial oversight are no less subject
to the pressures of the market than their clients.
Calls for greater control, which remain within the
framework of the capitalist economy and the profit
system, miss the essential point. The Enron debacle,
which has brought such economic devastation to the
lives of many thousands of people, is a symptom, not
the disease itself.
It is the outcome of a crisis in the capitalist economy
as a whole. The subordination of the production of
wealth to the extraction of private profit—the
basis of the capitalist economy—has now reached
such a state of decay that fraud and deception have
become its modus operandi.
Real control cannot be established by tightening accounting
rules and procedures. This is because accounting firms
themselves are major corporate players and the accounting
system itself is based on the very system of private
ownership and private profit which lies at the heart
of the crisis. Real control, in any case, can never
be exercised by a caste of administrators and officials.
It can only be established when society as a whole
and its members, the producers of all wealth, are
able to democratically determine how it shall be utilised
and developed. Such a social order presupposes the
establishment of social ownership of the means of
production. This is the central issue raised by the
Enron collapse.
MORE ON ENRON
>>
January 22, 2002.
[Source: www.wsws.org]
|