John
Maynard Keynes, though bourgeois in his outlook, was
a remarkably insightful economist, whose book Economic
Consequences of the Peace was copiously quoted by
Lenin at the Second Congress of the Communist International
to argue that conditions had ripened for the world
revolution. But even Keynes' insights could not fully
comprehend the paradox that is capitalism.
In a famous essay ''Economic Possibilities for our
Grandchildren'', written in 1930, Keynes had argued:
''Assuming no important wars and no important increase
in population, the economic problem may be solved,
or be at least within sight of solution, within a
hundred years. This means that the economic problem
is not, if we look into the future, the permanent
problem of the human race (emphasis in the original).
He had gone on to ask: ''Why, you may ask, is this
so startling? It is startling because, if instead
of looking into the future, we look into the past,
we find that the economic problem, the struggle for
subsistence, always has been hitherto the most pressing
problem of the human race… If the economic problem
is solved, mankind will be deprived of its traditional
purpose.'' He had then proceeded to examine how mankind
could fruitfully use its time in such a world.
True, after Keynes had written there has been the
Second World War, but thereafter mankind has had six
and a half decades without any ''important war'' of
the sort that could interrupt what he had called the
''era of progress and invention''. And the rate of population
growth has also not accelerated to a point that can
be considered to have invalidated Keynes' premise.
And yet if we take mankind as a whole, it is as far
from solving the economic problem as it ever was.
True, there has been massive accumulation of capital,
and with it an enormous increase in the mass of goods
available to mankind; and yet, for the vast majority
of mankind, the ''struggle for subsistence'' that Keynes
had referred to has continued to remain as acute as
ever, perhaps in some ways even more acute than ever
before.
To say that this is only because not enough time has
passed, that over a slightly longer time period Keynes'
vision will indeed turn out to be true, is facile.
The fact that the bulk of mankind continues to face
an acute struggle for subsistence is not a matter
of degree; it is not as if the acuteness of this struggle
for this segment of mankind has been lessening over
time, or that the relative size of this segment has
been lessening over time. We cannot therefore assert
that the passage of more time will lift everybody
above this struggle.
Likewise, to say that while enormous increases have
taken place in the mass of goods and services available
to mankind (the increase in this mass being more in
the last hundred years than in the previous two thousand
years, as Keynes had pointed out), its distribution
has been extremely skewed and hence accounts for the
persistence of the struggle for subsistence for the
majority of the world's population, is to state a
mere tautology. The whole point is that there is something
structural to the capitalist system itself, the same
system that causes this enormous increase in mankind's
capacity to produce goods and services, which also
ensures that, notwithstanding this enormous increase,
the struggle for subsistence must continue to be as
acute as before, or even more acute than before, for
the bulk of mankind.
Keynes missed this structural aspect of capitalism.
His entire argument in fact was based on the mere
logic of compound interest, i.e. on the sheer fact
that ''if capital increases, say, 2 percent per annum,
the capital equipment of the world will have increased
by a half in twenty years, and seven and a half times
in a hundred years''. From this sheer fact it follows
that output too would have increased more or less
by a similar order of magnitude, and mankind, with
so much more of goods at its disposal, would have
overcome the struggle for subsistence. The reason
Keynes assumed that an increase in the mass of goods
would eventually benefit everyone lies not just in
his inability to see the antagonistic nature of the
capitalist mode of production (and its antagonistic
relationship with the surrounding universe of petty
producers), but also in his belief that capitalism
is a malleable system which can be moulded, in accordance
with the dictates of reason, by the interventions
of the State as the representative of society. He
was a liberal and saw the state as standing above,
and acting on behalf of, society as a whole, in accordance
with the dictates of reason. The world, he thought,
was ruled by ideas; and correct, and benevolent, ideas
would clearly translate themselves into reality, so
that the increase in mankind's productive capacity
would get naturally transformed into an end of the
economic problem. If the antagonism of capitalism
was pointed out to Keynes, he would have simply talked
about state intervention restraining this antagonism
to ensure that the benefit of the increase in productive
capacity reached all.
The fact that this has not happened, the fact that
the enormous increase in mankind's capacity to produce
has translated itself not into an end to the struggle
for subsistence for the world's population, but into
a plethora of all kinds of goods and services of little
benefit to it, from a stockpiling of armaments to
an exploration of outer space, and even into a systematic
promotion of waste, and lack of utilization, or even
destruction, of productive equipment, only underscores
the limitations of the liberal world outlook of which
Keynes was a votary. The state, instead of being an
embodiment of reason, which intervenes in the interests
of society as a whole, as liberalism believes, acts
to defend the class interests of the hegemonic class,
and hence to perpetuate the antagonisms of the capitalist
system.
These antagonisms perpetuate in three quite distinct
ways the struggle for subsistence in which the bulk
of mankind is caught. The first centres on the fact
that the level of wages in the capitalist system depends
upon the relative size of the reserve army of labour.
And to the extent that the relative size of the reserve
army of labour never shrinks below a certain threshold
level, the wage rate remains tied to the subsistence
level despite significant increases in labour productivity,
as necessarily occur in the ''era of progress and innovation''.
Work itself therefore becomes a struggle for subsistence
and remains so. Secondly, those who constitute the
reserve army of labour are themselves destitute and
hence condemned to an even more acute struggle for
subsistence, to eke out for themselves an even more
meagre magnitude of goods and services. And thirdly,
the encroachment by the capitalist mode upon the surrounding
universe of petty production, whereby it displaces
petty producers, grabs land from the peasants, uses
the tax machinery of the State to appropriate for
itself, at the expense of the petty producers, an
amount of surplus value over and above what is produced
within the capitalist mode itself, in short, the entire
mechanism of ''primitive accumulation of capital'',
ensures that the size of the reserve army always remains
above this threshold level. There is a stream of destitute
petty producers forever flocking to work within the
capitalist mode but unable to find work and hence
joining the ranks of the reserve army. The antagonism
within the system, and vis-à-vis the surrounding
universe of petty production, thus ensures that, notwithstanding
the massive increases in mankind's productive capacity,
the struggle of subsistence for the bulk of mankind
continues unabated.
The growth rates of world output have been even greater
in the post-war period than in Keynes' time. The growth
rates in particular capitalist countries like India
have been of an order unimaginable in Keynes' time,
and yet there is no let up in the struggle for subsistence
on the part of the bulk of the population even within
these countries. In India, precisely during the period
of neo-liberal reforms when output growth rates have
been high, there has been an increase in the proportion
of the rural population accessing less than 2400 calories
per person per day (the figure for 2004 is 87 percent).
This is also the period when hundreds of thousands
of peasants, unable to carry on even simple reproduction
have committed suicide. The unemployment rate has
increased, notwithstanding a massive jump in the rate
of capital accumulation; and the real wage rate, even
of the workers in the organized sector, has at best
stagnated, notwithstanding massive increases in labour
productivity. In short our own experience belies the
Keynesian optimism about the future of mankind under
capitalism.
But Keynes wrote a long time ago. He should have seen
the inner working of the system better (after all
Marx who died the year Keynes was born, saw it), but
perhaps his upper class Edwardian upbringing came
in the way. But what does one say of people who, having
seen the destitution-''high growth'' dialectics in the
contemporary world, still cling to the illusion that
the logic of compound interest will overcome the ''economic
problem of mankind''? Neo-liberal ideologues of course
propound this illusion, either in its simple version,
which is the ''trickle down'' theory, or in the slightly
more complex version, where the State is supposed
to ensure through its intervention that the benefits
of the growing mass of goods and services are made
available to all, thereby alleviating poverty and
easing the struggle for subsistence.
But this illusion often appears in an altogether unrecognizable
form. Jeffrey Sachs, the economist who is well-known
for his administration of the so-called ''shock therapy''
in the former Soviet Union that led to a veritable
retrogression of the economy and the unleashing of
massive suffering on millions of people, has come
out with a book where he argues that poverty in large
parts of the world is associated with adverse geographical
factors, such as drought-proneness, desertification,
infertile soil, and such like. He wants global efforts
to help these economies which are the victims of such
niggardliness on the part of nature. The fact that
enormous poverty exists in areas, where nature is
not niggardly, but on the contrary bounteous; the
fact that the very bounteousness of nature has formed
the basis of exploitation of the producers on a massive
scale, so that they are engaged in an acute struggle
for existence precisely in the midst of plenitude;
and hence the fact that the bulk of the world's population
continues to struggle for subsistence not because
of nature's niggardliness but because of the incubus
of an exploitative social order, are all obscured
by such analysis. Keynes' faith in the miracle of
compound interest would be justified in a socialist
order, but not in a capitalist one.
February
4, 2011.
|