The
last quarter of the 19th century witnessed a period
of sustained global deflation. In the 1896 U.S. presidential
election, William Jennings Bryan famously attacked
the gold standard as the cause of deflation, declaring
''You shall not press upon the brow of labor this crown
of thorns. You shall not crucify mankind upon a cross
of gold.''
Today, Euroland is being crucified upon its own cross
of gold - the institutional arrangements behind the
euro. Those arrangements have distorted the monetary-fiscal
balance, creating deflationary central bank dominance.
That balance needs correction and failure to do so
could even risk the viability of the euro in its current
form.
The euro was introduced in 1999, the high-water mark
of neoliberal economics. As such, its institutional
design embeds neoliberal monetary theory which in
many regards rests on the same economic principles
as the gold standard. These principles are that fiscal
policy is ineffective; inflation is caused exclusively
by money supply growth; and the real economy quickly
and automatically returns to full employment in response
to negative shocks.
Principles discredited
All three principles have been fundamentally discredited
by the current recession. Around the world, countries
have turned to fiscal policy to offset the collapse
of private sector spending, and the recession would
have been far deeper absent that fiscal response.
Money supplies have risen dramatically almost everywhere
without matching increases in inflation, showing that
the money-inflation link is highly contingent upon
economic factors such as unemployment, capacity utilization,
commodity prices, and business expectations of profits.
Finally, rather than rebounding to full employment,
the global economy looks set for high unemployment
that will last years. This possibility was Keynes’
message in his 1936 General Theory.
Owing to its neoliberal monetary arrangements Euroland
has run smack into these economic realities. The European
monetary union (EMU) establishes central bank dominance
through an independent central bank that is prohibited
from providing financial assistance to member country
governments. Thus, whereas the US and UK have been
able to finance their fiscal and financial market
rescue plans with assistance from the Federal Reserve
and Bank of England respectively, eurozone governments
have received no equivalent assistance. Instead, they
have had to fend for themselves in private capital
markets, which has raised the costs of policy and
dissuaded more aggressive action.
Not only do these monetary arrangements contribute
to sub-optimal fiscal policy, they are also aggravating
fissures within Euroland. The periphery economies
of Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain, suffer from
high public debt, large budget deficits, high unemployment,
and lack of competitiveness. Capital markets are therefore
driving up periphery country bond rates and aggravating
their financial distress. Meanwhile, these economies
no longer have their own exchange rate or interest
rate to restore full employment and financial balance.
Consequently, their sole internal adjustment mechanism
is deflation, which is counter-productive in a situation
of high indebtedness.
Embrace expansion
Given this, the stronger European economies must embrace
expansion and act as an economic locomotive for the
periphery economies. But instead, the European monetary
system imposes a deflationary bias by restricting
fiscal space, while Germany has shown persistent recalcitrance
toward expansionary policies and exports deflationary
pressures.
Part of escaping this trap requires rebalancing monetary-fiscal
relations and increasing access to money-financed
fiscal policy. To this end the European Central Bank
(ECB) should establish annual country loan quotas
set according to each country’s economic size and
output gap, making them a form of automatic stabilizer.
This would create a mechanism for countries to monetize
part of their budget deficits. In the current environment
it would provide a flow of low-cost deficit financing
that would facilitate periphery country rebalancing,
while also providing an expansionary impulse in Europe’s
core economies.
Additionally, the ECB should establish emergency stand-by
country loan facilities that would be governed by
pre-determined policy conditionality. In effect, the
ECB would act as an analogue International Monetary
Fund (IMF) for euro member countries.
This has direct relevance for Greece’s current financial
crisis. Having Greece borrow from private capital
markets at exorbitant interest rates only compounds
the country’s financial burdens. Alternatively, having
the IMF bail out a euro-member country will damage
the euro’s standing as a reserve currency and it too
makes no sense. Greece needs euros to refinance its
debt and the ECB is the logical source given it is
the ultimate creator of euros.
Lastly, to counter potential inflationary consequences,
the ECB could be given discretion regarding distribution
of seignorage dividends resulting from issue of currency
and bank reserves.
Monetary reform alone will not bring prosperity to
Euroland. That will also require breaking with the
neoliberal approach to labour markets and macroeconomic
policy. However, monetary reform is a necessary ingredient
and absent such reform Euroland faces stagnation and
protracted high unemployment. Moreover, some financially
weaker member countries may be forced to exit the
euro because of financial market pressures or domestic
political discontent. Either way, this could have
potentially devastating global economic consequences,
which means all countries have an interest in EMU
reform.
This article was published in
the Financial Times, Economist Forum on 10 February
2010.
February
15, 2010.
|