As
global capitalism lurches around in crisis, it seems
that there is no end to the worms crawling out of
the woodwork. The financial crash and economic downswings
have been accompanied by more than just cyclical bad
news from companies that have been engaged in bona
fide business. The adverse market conditions are making
it harder to disguise corporate frauds that could
flourish in the earlier boom, and so more and more
details of unsavoury business operations are emerging
among a wide range of firms all over the world.
In India the Satyam scam may be grabbing the headlines,
but corporate frauds are likely to be uncovered in
many countries. In the leading capitalist economy,
the United States, such corporate frauds have been
rising sharply in recent years, according to data
from the official investigating agency, as the accompanying
chart shows. Between 2001 and 2007, the number of
corporate fraud cases that were opened by the FBI
(covering both corporate fraud per se and securities
and commodities fraud) increased by 43.7 per cent,
even though convictions barely increased. And in 2008,
the number of scandals that has come to light, and
the sheer extent and audacity of several of them,
almost defy description.
This ought to surprise us, because after the huge
corporate accounting scandals of the early part of
the decade, exemplified by the Enron scandal and the
subsequent exposure of significant firms like WorldCom,
Adelphia, Peregrine Systems and others, the US government
took steps to enact legislation that would regulate
corporate markets specifically to prevent such frauds.
The Sarbanes-Oxley Act that was passed by the US Congress
in 2002 (officially known as the Public Company Accounting
Reform and Investor Protection Act of 2002) was meant
to strengthen and tighten corporate accounting procedures.
It established a new quasi-public agency to oversee,
regulate, inspect and discipline accounting firms
in their roles as auditors of public companies. It
also specified tighter rules for corporate governance,
including internal control assessments and enhanced
financial disclosure.
Source:
Report of the Corporate Fraud Task Force, 2008, US
Government, Page 1.19
All this, it could be supposed, would operate to prevent
any future Enron-type scandals from occurring at all.
Indeed, those who opposed the act argued that it created
a complex over-regulated environment for US companies,
which reduced their competitive edge over foreign
firms. (However, a number of other countries – Japan,
Germany, France, Italy, Canada, as well as developing
countries like South Africa – have passed similar
legislation.)
Sarbanes-Oxley, or indeed any attempts to control
and regulate corporate behaviour especially in the
financial realm, have been much criticised by representatives
of large firms and by many market-friendly economists
as well. Consider this typical academic justification
for not regulating markets: “While corporate fraud
can impose significant costs of the economy when left
unchecked, the evidence shows that market mechanisms
discipline much bad behaviour while the criminalisation
of corporate behaviour, coupled with bringing highly
complex cases before juries that can neither understand
the issues nor their instructions, imposes significant
costs on the economy by deterring socially efficient
risk-taking behaviour by corporations and their executives...
The result is harm to the general public, whose members
depend on a dynamic, competitive economy for their
welfare.” (Howard H. Chang and David S. Evans, “Has
the pendulum swung too far?” Regulation, Vol. 30,
No. 4, Winter 2007-2008).
Yet it now turns out that, far from being too restrictive,
if anything the Sarbanes-Oxley Act was not effective
enough. After the spate of corporate financial scandals
that actually resulted in the collapse of several
companies in the early part of the decade, corporate
fraud has apparently continued almost unabated even
in the US. One reason for this may have been in the
design and implementation of the legislation, which
did not take in to account the crucial features of
such scams, and the structure of incentives that both
allowed and encouraged such malpractices to occur.
A quick look at some of the more famous of these corporate
frauds may illustrate this point. Consider first Enron,
the gigantic scam that has unfortunately set the bar
for all the other scandals that have followed since
2001. This was a financial scandal that could occur
because energy sector liberalisation and financial
deregulation in the US allowed for trading in electricity
and natural gas futures, partly because of intense
lobbying by Enron and similar firms. While the resulting
energy price volatility adversely affected consumers,
it delivered high speculative profits to what was
originally a power generation firm but rapidly became
dominantly an energy trading firm. Enron then created
as number of offshore subsidiaries, which provided
ownership and management with full freedom of currency
movement. This also allowed any losses in such trading
to be kept off the balance sheets.
As a result, Enron appeared to be much more profitable
than it actually was. Naturally its share price also
zoomed, allowing the managers to benefit from the
capital gains that they received from their employee-stock
options and performance-related bonuses. It is easy
to see how this created a dangerous spiral: those
handling the finances had major incentives (and then
increasingly felt extreme pressure) to cook the books
so as to show growing profits, even as the company
was actually losing money.
As the dotcom boom in the US finally went bust in
2000, it became even harder for Enron’s managers to
carry own with this creative accounting, until at
last it became impossible to keep up the pretence.
Ultimately the company could not even be restructured
but had to be liquidated. Thousands of Enron employees
lost not only their jobs, but also their savings and
pensions, which were tied up in company stock. Fourteen
of the company’s managers were accused, faced trial
and sentenced on various charges of fraud, misleading
the public, insider trading and other malfeasance.
The role of the auditing company – Arthur Andersen,
one of the then Big-Five accounting companies – obviously
came under scrutiny. Remarkably, however, it was found
that it could not be held legally responsible for
what was clearly criminal negligence and dereliction
of duty over a prolonged period. Instead, the only
charge that could be brought against it was obstruction
of justice, for shredding documents related to its
audit of Enron. And even that was overturned by the
Supreme Court in 2005 on grounds of flaws in the instructions
to the jury! However, because the US Securities and
Exchange Commission did not allow it to audit public
companies, it could not retain viable business and
the company collapsed.
Another scandal of that period that has even more
similarities to the Satyam case is that of Adelphia
Communications Company, which was earlier celebrated
as a rags-to-riches story of two brothers (John and
Timothy Rigas) who had originally founded the company
on the basis of a $300 cable license. When the company
declared bankruptcy in 2003 because it was forced
to disclose more than $2 billion in off-balance-sheet
debt, it emerged that the Rigas brothers had used
complex financial and cash management practices to
transfer money to various other family-owned entities.
In addition, federal prosecutors successfully accused
them of salting away at least $100 million personally.
Similarly, the Refco case related to what would earlier
be called straightforward embezzlement but is now
seen as a complex system of sophisticated financial
irregularities. Refco, a finance company that specialised
in commodities and futures contracts, was a private
company that went public in the August 2005. Its share
prices immediately rose by more than 25 per cent because
of its apparent history of high profitability. In
October 2005, just before its collapse, it was the
largest broker on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange.
Refco’s downfall came about when it emerged that its
Chief Executive Officer, Richard Bennett, had hidden
about $430 million of bad debts from both the rest
of the company’s board and its auditors. He was able
to do this through the simple and ridiculous expedient
of buying bad debts from Refco, so as to prevent the
company from having to write them off, and then paying
for these bad loans with money borrowed by the company
itself!
What is most extraordinary about the Refco case is
that this fraud was revealed only a few months after
the company had made its first initial public offering
(IPO) of shares. Before such a public listing, due
diligence and detailed examination of accounts is
required of the investment banks that manage the IPO.
In Refco’s case, the IPO was handled by the top names
in banking: Goldman Sachs, Credit Suisse First Boston,
and Bank of America. Yet none of them had uncovered
this huge hole of $430 million in bad debt that the
CEO declared within a couple of months, nor had they
even noticed the peculiar practice that the CEO had
used to cover it up. So in this instance it was not
just the auditors (the smaller accounting company
Grant Thornton) that were found to be lax and inadequate
to the task. While Richard Bennett was sentenced to
16 years in prison in 2008, no action was taken against
any of the others involved who had been at best very
derelict in their duty.
In Brian Cruver’s famous book on the Enron case, The
Anatomy of Greed, a senior manager is quoted as saying
“Don't think it's just this company. There's hundreds
of Enrons out there, a thousand, cooking the books,
inflating the earnings, hiding the debt, buying off
the watchdogs.” There have been so many instances
of corporate fraud since then, both in the US and
elsewhere, ranging from Parmalat Spa in Europe to
Tyco International in the US. And this excludes the
pure Ponzi schemes such as the recently exposed one
run by Bernie Madoff, whereby investors are paid returns
that are no more than investments by subsequent investors,
rather than any actual profit.
In so many of these cases, the auditors involved have
been among the major accounting firms in the world.
In addition to the now-dissolved Arthur Andersen,
all the following firms have been implicated several
times in corporate fraud: Deloitte and Touche, Ernst
and Young, KPMG, and of course PriceWaterhouseCoopers,
made infamous in India because they were the auditors
of Satyam Computers. Yet the system as a whole continues
to rely upon these incompetent companies.
This completely contradicts the “efficient markets
hypothesis” that underlies so much financial liberalisation.
This argument, along with the doctrines of the mainstream
“law and economics” discussion, generally underplays
the possibility and significance of fraud, because
of a perception that “market discipline” will prevent
it and a belief that mala fide actions cannot subvert
the market mechanism beyond a point.
So then how can these frauds happen? And what is the
economic logic of such a system that is so completely
susceptible to fraud? This is explained beautifully
by William K. Black in his brilliant expose of the
Savings and Loan scandal in the US in the early 1980s,
“The Best Way to Rob a Bank Is to Own One: How corporate
executives and politicians looted the S&L industry”
(University of Texas Press 2005).
This book has been described as a classic by the Nobel
Prize-winning economist George Akerlof. Black’s analysis
is a dissection of “control fraud”, when the organisation
is the vehicle for perpetrating crime against itself.
This calculated dishonesty to loot a company in pursuit
of personal profit by those at the helm of corporate
affairs could also be termed “collective embezzlement”..
He shows how this is much more pervasive than is generally
suspected, and indeed could be endemic to the system,
especially when it is characterised by lax regulation
and casual oversight. He shows how such frauds tend
to occur in waves that make financial markets deeply
inefficient.
Therefore, control fraud is a major, ongoing threat
in business that requires active, independent regulators
to contain it. Yet neoliberal market-oriented policies
have typically operated to reduce the capacity for
effective regulation in four characteristic ways.
His argument is so plausible and still so unnervingly
relevant that it deserves quotation in some detail:
“First, the policies limit the number and quality
of regulators. Second, the policies limit the power
of regulators. It is common for the profits of control
fraud to greatly exceed the maximum allowable penalties.
Third, it is common to choose lead regulators that
do not believe in regulation (Harvey Pitt as Chairman
of the SEC and, more generally, President Reagan’s
assertion that “government is the problem”). Fourth,
it is common to choose, or retain, corrupt regulatory
leaders. Privatisation, for example, creates ample
opportunities, resources, and incentive to corrupt
regulators.
Neo-classical economic policy further aggravates systems
capacity problems by advising that the deregulation,
desupervision and privatisation take place very rapidly
and be radical. These recommendations guarantee that
even honest, competent regulators will be overwhelmed.
Overall, the invariable result is a self-fulfilling
policy – regulation will fail. Discrediting regulation
may be part of the plan, or the result may be perverse
unintended consequences.
Neo-classical policies also act perversely by easing
neutralisation. Looting control frauds are guaranteed
to produce large, fictional profits. Neo-classical
proponents invariably cite these profits as proof
that the ‘reforms’ are working and praise the ‘entrepreneurs’
that produced the profits. Simultaneously, there is
a rise in Social Darwinism. The frauds claim that
the profits prove their moral superiority and the
necessity of not using public funds to keep inefficient
workers employed. The frauds become the most famous
and envied members of high society and use the company’s
funds to make political and charitable contributions
(and conspicuous consumption) to make them dominant.
In sum, in every way possible, neo-classical policies,
when they are adopted wholesale, sow the seeds of
their own destruction by bringing about a wave of
control fraud. Control frauds are a disaster on many
different levels. They produce enormous losses that
society (already poor in many instances) must bear.
They corrupt the government and discredit it. They
inherently distort the market and make it less efficient.
When they produce bubbles they drive the market into
deep inefficiency and can produce economic stagnation
once the bubble collapses. They eat away at trust.”
Does this sound familiar and relevant to the present
times? Yet this insightful argument has been in the
public domain for several years, and has still been
ignored by those involved in pushing the neo-liberal
policies that create the potential for such frauds.
This has been one of the main reasons why the Sarbanes-Oxley
Law has not worked to control corporate malpractice
in the US.
Ultimately the lack of public awareness, and therefore
of systematic political pressure to prevent it, has
allowed the cosy relationship between regulators and
corporate leaders to create this fraudulent crony
capitalism. And it is also why the rest of us in other
countries are also more and more exposed to the negative
effects of such fraud.
February
2 , 2009.
|