Remember
the East Asia crisis, when the US treasury and its
IMF allies blamed that region's problems on
crony capitalism, lack of transparency, and poor corporate
governance?
Countries were told to follow the American model,
use American auditing firms, bring in American entrepreneurs
to teach them how to run their companies. (Never mind
that under the leadership of their own entrepreneurs
East Asia grew faster than any other region —
and with greater stability — over the previous
three decades.) The unfolding Enron scandal brings
new meaning to two favourite American sayings: "What
goes around comes around,'' and "People
in glass houses shouldn't throw stones.''
Enron used fancy accounting tricks and complicated
financial products (derivatives) to mislead investors
about its value. No transparency here. It used its
money to buy influence and power, shape US energy
policy, and avoid regulations.
Crony capitalism is not new; nor is it the province
of a single party. Former US treasury secretary Robert
Rubin reportedly tried to influence the current government
to intervene on behalf of Enron in its hotly contested
dispute in India. In office, he had intervened when
the supposedly independent board for setting accounting
standards tried to clean up the accounting of senior
executives' share options.
Partly thanks to him, this effort to make corporate
accounting more transparent was stymied. America's
willingness to provide multi-billion dollar bail-outs
to airlines or to create cartels to protect its steel
and aluminium industries suggests that free market
ideology is but a thin guise for old-fashioned corporate
welfare: give to those with the appropriate connections.
To some, the fact that Enron was not bailed out and
the problems uncovered, is testimony to the absence
of crony capitalism. I have a different interpretation:
it is testimony to the importance of a free press,
which may not stop but can curtail abuses. As the
press started taking a closer look at Enron, the number
of members of Congress who had accepted money from
Enron became clear. Campaign contributions were not
just a matter of public spirit, but an investment.
Like many of Enron's investments, it worked
well in the short run, but did not pan out in the
long run.
Many lessons emerge. Some concern politics: the Enron
scandal strengthens the case for campaign finance
reform, and the need for even stronger laws requiring
public disclosure. Democracies are undermined by corporate
interests being able to, in effect, buy elections.
The Bush administration, however, refuses to disclose
information which would show the role of corporate
interests in setting its energy policy.
Other lessons concern economics, especially the economics
of information. For markets to work, for the appropriate
signals for efficient resource allocation to be provided,
investors must have as much information as possible.
There are inherent conflicts of interest: owners and
managers have a natural incentive to present a picture
as rosy as possible. Auditing is intended to put limits
on potential abuses. But who is to guard the guardians?
Who is to audit the auditors?
We rely heavily on incentives. Auditors desire to
maintain their reputation. But the interlinking of
consulting and auditing practices puts other perverse
incentives in place: an incentive to please the clients,
who dislike unfavourable reports. Arthur Levitt, the
former chairman of the Securities and Exchange Commission,
recognised the conflict: as many within the auditing
firms focus on their own short-term interests, the
integrity of the audits could be compromised.
He is perhaps the unsung hero of the entire debacle.
But the auditing firms and their corporate clients
— not surprisingly, given the cabal that developed
— roundly attacked his proposal for separating
consulting from auditing. What Levitt grasped —
and what the Enron debacle shows so clearly —
is that incentives matter, but that unfettered markets
by themselves may not provide the right incentives.
Markets may not provide incentives for wealth creation;
they may provide incentives for the kind of shenanigans
Enron pursued.
The new economy — and its complicated new financial
instruments — enhance the problems of reliable
accounting frameworks; they make it easier to obfuscate.
Rather than facing up to the issues, corporate America
systematically turns its back — aided and abetted
by crony capitalism, American style.
The central issue of our time is finding the right
balance between the government and the market. The
status quo will argue that Enron is an exception:
that its demise was due to fraud, that we have laws
against fraud, and that those who violate these laws
should and will bear the consequences. But much of
what Enron did was not illegal. Its auditors claim
that its central practices were within the law; that
thousands of firms do the same.
They are right — and that's the problem.
Investors need assurance that information received
adequately reflects the economic situation of a firm.
Within the current regulatory and legal environment,
with derivatives and other off-balance-sheet liabilities,
there is no way for investors to have that assurance
today. We need better standards and stronger laws.
While we will never be able to prevent all abuses,
we can get the incentives right. We can try to inculcate
better ethical standards. But we cannot rely on them
when so many worldly people see nothing wrong with
revolving doors. They claim to manage conflicts of
interest; but we see that they may manage them for
their own interests. But even as evidence for such
abuses becomes apparent, new venues for abuse are
repeatedly opened up — take the US repeal of
the Glass Steagall Act, which separated commercial
from investment banking.
Repeatedly, we have seen the consequences of the
excesses of deregulation, of unfettered markets. Now
we must resist the temptation to go to the other extreme.
The challenge is: get the balance right.
(The author is Professor of Economics at Columbia
University, and former senior vice president of the
World Bank)
MORE ON ENRON
>>
February 18, 2002.
[Source: The Economic Times, February 16, 2002]
|