In the course of the debate on the need for permitting
foreign investment in retail in India, two arguments
have been often advanced. The first was that large
organized retail is good not just for consumers who
would benefit from lower prices due to cost efficiencies
and competition, but also for farmers who would be
the beneficiaries of stable demand for their produce
at reasonable prices. The second was that the segment
of large retail that would be able to deliver these
benefits to consumers and producers would be the international
retail giants with deep pockets and experience of
structuring the supply chain to deliver these benefits.
This case that the presence or entry of international
retail giants helps ensure reasonable prices for the
consumer, remunerative prices for producers and profits
for the intermediary is ostensibly based on the international
experience in both developed and developing country
contexts. This is indeed surprising since in practice
the relative gains derived by participants in market
economies is known to depend on the market power of
the participants concerned. Besides the fact that
the international retail giants would by their very
definition be powerful, the structure of the supply
chain varies across counties.
Consider the food economy for example. Within the
US the supply chain has at one end an industrial agriculture
with large farmers known to be subsidised substantially
by the American government and at the other the end
the large retailers who have control over significant
segments of the supply chain from farm to table. Concentration
in the retail trade has increased substantially. The
share of the top 8 stores in total US grocery store
sales increased from 26 per cent in 1992 to 50 per
cent in 2009. That of the top 20 from 39 to 64 per
cent.
In other countries including most developing countries
the structure is more complex. Foreign chains have
entered and have been expanding, but the retail space
is still shared between the traditional retailers
and the modern chains. An abiding feature of the experience
with this kind of system has been that the appearance
of the large, modern chains does not lead to the upgradation
of the traditional, unorganised retail sector, but
to its being bypassed with attendant implications
for employment and livelihoods. This dualism, which
sees quality and environmental standards languishing
in unorganised retail then becomes the basis for its
displacement by larger organised retail as incomes
rise.
Since the US is the typical case of the operation
of organised retail, it is here that its effects at
both ends of the chain should be visible. The scene
is, however, distorted by the subsidies for agriculture,
which remain large and have not fallen after the implementation
of the Agreement on Agriculture under the Uruguay
Round. However, these subsidies are partly needed
because the giant retail chains that dominate the
procurement and distribution of food products have
enhanced their margins at the expense of farmers.
Aggregate food expenditures in the US rose from $833.2
billion in 2000 to 1.2 trillion in 2009, or by an
absolute $370 billion. On the other hand, cash receipts
from farm marketing increased from $197.6 billion
to $282.2 billion or by $85 billion. These divergent
levels and trends can be explained by the costs of
processing, the margins for marketing, and the profits
associated with large, organized retailing. During
the 2000 to 2009 period, for example, the USDA estimates
that the farm share of the retail price fluctuated
between 23 and 28 per cent in the case of fresh vegetables
and 25 and 30 per cent in the case of fresh fruits.
Not all of that huge difference can be attributed
to processing costs, transportation and storage. According
to one estimate advertising, rent, interest and profits
accounted for 15 cent of every dollar spent on food.
But these are in normal times. An analysis after the
food crisis of the 1990s had this to say: "Farmers
can see themselves being reduced from their mythological
status as independent producers to a subservient and
vulnerable role as sharecroppers or franchisees. The
control of food production, both livestock and crops,
is being consolidated not by the government but by
a handful of giant corporations. While farmers and
ranchers suffered three years of severely depressed
prices at the close of the 1990s, the corporations
enjoyed soaring profits from the same line of goods.
Growers are surrounded now on both sides - facing
concentrated market power not only from the companies
that buy their crops and animals but also from the
firms that sell them essential inputs like seeds and
fertiliser. In the final act of unfettered capitalism,
the free market itself is destroyed." (William
Grieder, "The last farm crisis", The Nation,
November 20, 2000)
The situation in Europe, where smaller retailer have
not been completely wiped out, is also telling. According
to an official report prepared in June this year by
the French government's food price watchdog, the profit
margins on food sold in supermarkets are hugely inflated.
By comparing the prices charged to customers with
the wholesale prices charged by producers, the report
argued that the supermarkets were squeezing producers
by paying lower prices, but were not passing on the
gains to to customers. Moreover, when wholesale prices
fell, customers ended up paying just as much or even
more. Margins on apples and bananas stood at margins
around 140%, and for carrots and lettuce at 110 per
cent. The margin on pork loin had risen to 55% from
39% a decade ago.
In developing countries, such as those in Asia where
the supermarket revolution has been underway for some
time now, the evidence is that competition hurts producers
most. Concerned with quality and standardisation,
the chains look for ''preferred suppliers'' who can
ensure regular supplies. But while the investments
needed for realising these tends to be high for small
farmers, competition among them to tie up with a chain
keeps prices down. In East Asia, the supermarket share
of retail food sales had ballooned from less than
20 percent to around 50 percent over the decade ending
around 2005. In the process, small farmers were squeezed
out since supermarkets tended to sub-contract only
to a few large suppliers that can meet their demands
on quality, standardized production and quantity.
Over a short period of less than 5 years, Thailand's
leading supermarket chain reportedly slashed its list
of vegetable suppliers from 250 down to 10, cutting
out the small farmers.
In the event, farmers who are supposed to benefit
are put under huge pressure as they have to meet the
changing requirements and standards, or eventually
exit from farming. Meeting standards for quality and
reliability requires high levels of investment in
irrigation, transportation, storage facilities and
packaging technology. But this requires technology,
access to credit, training and information. As a result
the poorest producers who constitute the majority
lose out in a market that increasingly monopolized
by the supermarkets.
Thus, a study conducted five years back in Asia by
the Food and Agriculture Organisation argued that
''fierce competition among supermarket chains forces
them to seek ever lower product and transaction costs
and to minimize risk. For producers, this means that
the chains will not contribute to the kind of farm-level
investments needed if small farmers are to participate
in new markets. The squeeze on farmers' margins is
likely to tighten as supermarkets become as concerned
with safety and quality as they are now with cost.''
Thus, irrespective of the structure of retail markets
overall, the presence of the large international giants
does not help all producer and consumers, but harms
many of them. The worst hit are the poorest of producers.
The global experience by no means tallies with the
presumptions on which the UPA government's FDI-in-retail
policy is based.
* This article was originally
published in the Frontline, Volume 28 - Issue 26 ::
Dec. 17-30, 2011.
December
26, 2011.
|