As the major developed economies struggle
with sluggish growth and the prospects for developing countries have been
inevitably affected by such deflationary pressures, the UNCTAD's latest
Trade and Development Report for 2003 offers some distinct insights into
the current global economic predicament.
The first part of the Report shows how the recovery of global economic
activity after its sharp decline in 2001 has been much slower and more
erratic than expected. It traces this back to the pattern of global trade
and financial flows in the 1990s, leading up to an increased dependence
on the US economy as the main source of global growth. This in turn is
fundamentally related to the changes that occurred in the underlying economic
policy regimes, particularly across the developing world. Thus, in part
II, the Report analyses why the market-led economic policy reforms adopted
in many developing countries subsequent to the debt crisis of the early
1980s have not improved their growth and industrial performance, or strengthened
their ability to withstand external shocks. The Report provides explanations
that challenge conventional points of view and raises concerns about the
current direction of global economic policymaking dogmatically driven
by proponents of the neo-liberal economic paradigm.
The State of the World Economy
TDR 2003 makes revealing assessments of the state of the global economy
and the problems of the prevailing economic policymaking. It presents
the grim prospect that the imbalances and excesses created during the
high-tech boom of the 1990s could result in a long period of erratic and
sluggish growth, with occasional surges and dips accompanied by price
deflation.
When the high-tech stock market boom in the US ended in the first half
of 2000, there were widespread expectations of a short and sharp recession.
Contrary to such expectations, the US economy entered a more persistent
but less severe slowdown. Growth in Europe and Japan, on the other hand,
instead of accelerating to offset the slowdown in the US, actually fell
in 2002.
The Report attributes the delay in vigorous recovery in the US economy
primarily to the failure of investment spending to recover, because of
continued excess capacity remaining from the end-nineties' boom in the
information and telecommunications sectors. Against this failure of an
expected strong recovery in the US, preserving the growth of global income
and international trade would require a rapid shift in the policies in
the rest of the industrialized world. However, measures to stimulate domestic
demand from the major countries in Europe and Japan have been short in
coming. This has made the global recovery process more difficult.
A major factor behind the failure of Europe's recovery has been the increasing
difficulty of implementing a counter-cyclical economic policy within the
rigid monetary and fiscal constraints set for the Euro area. The increased
interdependence of EU activity with that in the US, arising from the large
number of mergers and acquisitions between European and US firms in the
1990s, has also contributed to the difficulties in stimulating European
recovery. In Japan, on the other hand, despite the Bank of Japan's policy
of zero interest rates, deflation continued unabated. As a result, the
financial sector continued to reflect weaknesses, and the Japanese economy
too started to contract again in the first quarter of 2003, pulling back
global recovery.
The consequences of the global economic slowdown in 2002 inevitably affected
the developing world, even though there were significant variations both
between and within regions. In general, the latter can be linked to the
differences in the policy choices made by them.
The East Asian region as a whole proved less susceptible than anticipated
to the effects of the weaknesses in the industrialized world in 2002.
However, with a sharp drop in growth or outright recession in most of
the major economies in the region, output declined in Latin America in
2002, for the first time since the 1980s. On the other hand, performance
in Africa was largely independent of the impact of the US downturn in
2001 and more closely linked to demand conditions in Europe. Thus, the
region benefited little from the upswing in 2002, and climatic and political
conditions continued to have a major impact on economic performance. The
transition economies were also less affected by the global slowdown, inspite
of the fact that many of these economies belonging to the Eastern Europe
and the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) have high dependence
on trade with Western Europe.
Capital Accumulation, Economic Growth and Structural
Change- The Debate on Development Strategies
Given the increased diversity in economic performance among developing
countries in the current global economic downturn, TDR opens afresh the
debate on latecomer industrialisation and growth strategies facing developing
countries. Given that the most notable success stories in catching-up
industrialisation since the Second World War have been in East Asia, the
discussion inevitably centres on the growth experiences of the first-tier
and second-tier newly industrialising economies (NIEs) of the region and
looks at the policy lessons they have to offer vis-à-vis the Latin
American economies. As always, the analysis brought out by TDR makes a
departure from the other main publication from the UNCTAD secretariat,
the World Investment Report.
It is known that during the entire period 1960-1990, the countries in
East Asia had enjoyed rapid, uninterrupted and stable growth, which was
also remarkably stable. Growth slowed down and instability increased only
during the 1990s and clearly reflected the boom-bust cycles associated
with unstable capital flows. While this culminated in the 1997-98 crisis,
most of these countries have managed a fairly rapid turnaround subsequently.
By contrast, the growth performance of the Latin American region, whose
growth rates and per capita income levels were similar to that of the
East Asian region between 1960 and 1973, diverged sharply and became increasingly
unstable after that. In fact, subsequent to the adoption of the economic
reforms, most of these countries experienced slower and less stable growth
during 1980-2000 than in the previous two decades. Further, at present,
Latin American countries have appreciating currencies just when there
is a global economic slowdown in output and trade, and are faced with
a shift to short-term capital flows once again. Against the backdrop of
the instability of such short-term capital inflows, the recovery in Latin
America in 2003 is thus also likely to be weak and fragile.
TDR highlights how the neoliberal reforms adopted in the Latin American
economies subsequent to the debt crisis (collectively referred to as the
"Washington Consensus") were aimed at removing structural and
institutional impediments to growth and imcreasing allocative efficiency,
and thus improve productive capacity and trade performance. The argument
of the proponents of these reforms has been that the removal of domestic
price distortions and the freeing of market forces would generate rapid
increases in private investment. Specifically, increasing investment was
to be achieved through the mobilization of domestic savings through deregulation,
liberalization of the financial sector, and attraction of foreign direct
investment (FDI). This was expected to put an end to the stop-go development
cycles associated with excessive indebtedness and periodic BOP crises,
and usher in an era of sustained growth and poverty reduction. But, the
Latin American growth experience and their increased vulnerability to
BOP crises as seen in the last two decades, discredit any claims of the
neoliberal growth paradigm in meeting these professed objectives.
Although the ultimate aim of the macroeconomic and other measures implemented
in the countries that experienced the debt crisis was to prepare the ground
for private investment-led recoveries, a rapid and sustained recovery
in capital accumulation and growth has proved elusive for most of the
countries undergoing rapid market reforms, in both Latin America and Africa.
In fact, the "investment pause" that followed the debt crisis
of the early 1980s has become a much more permanent feature of the economic
scene of many developing countries.
Industrial progress has also halted in much of the developing world; only
eight of 26 selected countries succeeded in raising the share of manufacturing
value added in GDP between 1980 and the 1990s. In particular, almost all
Latin American countries saw significant declines in the share of manufacturing
value added in GDP following the introduction (or intensification) of
market-based economic reforms since the 1970s and 1980s. By contrast,
policy continuity in East Asia after the debt crisis produced a strong
investment performance, and has lead to an increase in manufacturing value
added, employment and exports.
Given that after so many years of reform and adjustment, there is little
sign of creative forces initiating a new virtuous process of accumulation,
growth and structural change, the deindustrialisation process associated
with the shift in development paradigm in Latin America and sub-Saharan
Africa surely calls for a serious rethinking of the development strategies
adopted by developing countries. The TDR thus goes into the reasons of
why leaving enterprise to the invisible hand of global market forces,
as propounded by the prevailing paradigm, has failed in the rapid reformers.
It argues that capital accumulation holds the central place in the mutually
reinforcing interplay of linkages among capital accumulation, technological
progress and structural change, which constitute the basis for rapid and
sustained productivity growth and thus make up a virtuous growth regime.
Thus, identification of the factors that govern investment decisions is
the key to understanding the varying economic performance of developing
countries.
Industrialisation, Trade and Structural Change
Drawing attention to the contrasts between the Asian and Latin American
investment regimes, the Report points out how a strong relationship between
a rising ratio of investment to GDP constitutes an integral part of a
virtuous investment dynamic in most East Asian countries. On the contrary,
weak recoveries in Latin America is observed to have often been associated
with stronger performances in less productive categories such as housing
construction, along with a sharp decline in public investment in infrastructure.
This also gets reflected in the fact that for most Latin American countries,
there has been no improvement in the level or composition of investment,
even when FDI increased. In Asia, by contrast, recent surges in FDI inflows
have been associated with a rising share of investment in GDP and increased
investment in machinery and equipment. Thus, varying investment performance
is a major reason for the differences in the ability of developing countries
to establish and sustain a strong development path.
TDR 2003 then goes on to show how the close correlation between high investment
rates, rising shares of manufacturing in GDP and strong export performance
is underpinned by a rapid growth in productivity. Foreign trade also exerts
an important influence on the evolution of economic structure, in so far
as it can help to overcome domestic supply-side and demand-side constraints
on industrialisation and growth. However, as with investment, the extent
to which trade feeds into a more or less dynamic and virtuous industrialisation
process owes a good deal to policy choices and interventions.
This is because the links between investment on the one hand, and productivity
growth and trade performance on the other are not automatic. The pace
of productivity growth in developing countries and the speed with which
the productivity gap with developed countries can be reduced are affected
by: the nature of their participation in international production networks
(IPNs); technology and capital goods imports; and the process of learning
and adaptation fundamental to technological progress. Thus, targeted technology
policies also have a direct bearing on the outcome.
This is why while many developing countries are becoming increasingly
similar to developed countries in the structure of their manufactured
exports; this does not necessarily imply a corresponding similarity in
their pattern of manufacturing value added. This disparity between the
growth rates of manufacturing value added and exports is due to the weak
growth in domestic value added and to strong growth in imports associated
with participation in IPNs. Participation in IPNs is often advocated as
a possible basis for technological leapfrogging and rapid acceleration
of productivity growth. However, it has been established that the technology
transfer and learning processes in such networks are increasingly circumscribed
by the global strategies of TNCs, rather than by the national development
strategies of the host countries, as has been argued by the proponents
pushing for domestic economic policy and institutional reforms. This is
what leads to weak backward and forward linkages, which reduces the scope
for expansion in domestic value added.
Thus, it is rightly emphasised that the pace and pattern of industrialisation
are greatly influenced both by the pace and pattern of capital accumulation
and the nature of participation of countries in international trade. The
mutually reinforcing dynamic interactions between capital accumulation
and exports are believed to lead to successful industrialisation in developing
countries.
Analysing the processes of accumulation, industrialisation, trade and
structural change, the Report comes out with a classification of five
broad categories of developing countries:
1. The first group consists of first-tier NIEs, notably the Republic of
Korea and Taiwan Province of China, which have already achieved a considerable
degree of industrial maturity through a rapid accumulation of capital,
and growth in industrial employment, productivity, output, as well as
in manufactured exports. In both economies, the share of industrial output
is well above the levels of advanced industrial countries, but the pace
of expansion of production capacity and output in the industrial sector
has slowed down compared to the previous decades.
2. The second group consists of countries that are progressing rapidly
in industrialisation. They are increasing the share of manufacturing sector
in total employment, output and exports as well as upgrading from resource-based
and labour-intensive products to medium- and high-tech products in both
output and trade. These include the dynamic second-tier NIEs, notably
Malaysia and Thailand. China and to a lesser extent, India could also
be considered in this group, even though they are earlier stages of industrialisation
compared to the former.
3. The third group comprises countries that have rapidly integrated into
IPNs by focusing on simple assembly operations in labour-intensive manufactures.
They have seen a sharp rise in industrial employment and manufactured
exports, but their performance in terms of investment, manufacturing value
added and productivity growth, as well as overall economic growth has
been poor. Two countries that stand out in this group are Mexico and the
Philippines.
4. The fourth group comprises countries that have reached a certain level
of industrialisation, but have been unable to sustain a dynamic process
of industrial deepening in the context of rapid growth. These include
Brazil and Argentina, where investment performance has been poor, industry
has been losing its relative importance in total employment and value
added, productivity growth has been due to labour shedding rather than
faster accumulation and technical progress, industrial upgrading has been
limited, and exports have continued to be dominated by primary products
and low value-added manufactures. In these countries, although progress
has been achieved in certain industries such as aerospace and automobiles,
it has not gone deep enough to establish a dynamic momentum in the industries.
The African countries, at a much lower level of industrial development,
can also be included in this group, in terms of sluggish progress in their
industrialisation and structural change.
5. A final category consists of countries that have achieved sustained
and strong growth by intensifying exploitation of their rich natural resources
through a rapid pace of capital accumulation. However, their industrial
performance has been weak both in terms of manufacturing value added and
exports, and prospects for further structural change and productivity
growth appear to be limited. The most outstanding example is Chile.
Such evidence examined in Part II of the Report clearly shows that the
neoliberal reforms have failed in exactly the same areas in which previous
policies of import substitution had also failed. Unlike the advanced industrial
economies and the East Asian NIEs, the deindustrialisation trend in many
developing countries in Latin America and sub-Saharan Africa has not been
a benign product of differential productivity growth and structural change
in the context of steady economic expansion. Rather, it has coincided
with a widespread slowdown in growth.
Thus, it is clear that the support and protection given during the import-substituting
industrialisation of the 1960s and 1970s had undoubtedly allowed industry
in Latin America and to a lesser extent in Africa, to expand considerably
faster than would have been possible under competitive conditions. Unlike
in East Asia, however, which also made extensive use of industrial policies,
these strategies in Latin America and Africa were not always able to promote
viable industries. Consequently, with big-bang liberalisation and the
withdrawal of support and protection, confronted with stiff competition,
industries in these regions were forced to downsize, rationalise or perish.
However, with the failure of the first generation of reforms to deliver
on its promises, as TDR discusses, attention has turned to "getting
the investment climate right". This would be achieved by combining
macroeconomic stability with better business organization, improved 'governance',
and measures to boost competition for ensuring the 'quality' of investment.
This reintroduction of investment into the mainstream does not however
imply a fundamental departure from the earlier focus on market-driven
efficiency. Rather, strong emphasis has been placed on the role of competition
in promoting investment and economic growth, and this is to be attained
not only through further deregulation of domestic market, but through
even greater openness to international trade and investment. But, TDR
is unequivocal in its assertion that no unconditional link has been established
between greater openness and economic growth, either theoretically or
empirically.
Overall, the TDR is unambiguous in its preference for the strategy followed
by East Asian countries whose integration occurred from a position of
strength and was characterised by a continuous and purposeful strategy
of gradual opening up. A wide range of macroeconomic, financial and trade
policies were used in East Asia to stimulate investment, target industrial
upgrading and encourage exporting. By contrast, the shift in development
strategies that occurred in Latin America and Africa occurred in a period
of weakness in the aftermath of the debt crisis. The big-bang liberalization
they had to adopt has led to inconsistencies among macroeconomic, trade,
FDI and financial policies, which have skewed structural changes and stunted
technological progress.
Thus, East Asia's better performance is attributed to the better flexibility
and resilience of their productive structures, institutions and government
policies to respond to external shocks with effectiveness and vigour than
by Latin American countries. This has enabled most of the East Asian economies,
when exposed to external shocks, to adjust and continue, after a brief
pause, on their high growth paths. The importance of developing a broad
domestic industrial base to respond to development challenges derives
from its potential for strong productivity and income growth.
In fact, in 2002, the East Asian region as a whole proved less susceptible
than anticipated to the effects of the weaknesses in the industrialized
world. The Report attributes this to their low dependence on short-term
capital inflows, which has allowed them greater leeway for counter-cyclical
economic policy. However, this explanation seems problematic, as the reduced
short-term capital inflows to the region has largely not been the outcome
of deliberate policy decisions by the governments concerned in terms of
reducing their reliance on external capital. Rather, East Asia's recent
lesser reliance on short-term capital flows has been a reflection of the
fact that foreign portfolio investors have not returned en masse to the
region in the aftermath of the crisis. For some of these countries, reduced
net capital inflows has also been due to the repayments on the multilateral
loans taken by these countries subsequent to the financial crisis.
Growth in private consumption expenditure has been seen to be a more important
factor in explaining the region's recent growth. What is not highlighted
is the fact that the expansion in domestic demand, even in the countries
that took IMF loans in the aftermath of the crisis, was brought about
with non-orthodox expansionary policies, instead of following the IMF's
restrictive policy prescriptions. This recovery of domestic demand growth
also enabled expansion of the capacities bought over by foreign direct
investors through M&As, in both productive and financial sectors of
the crisis-ridden economies. This together with the expansion of intraregional
trade, especially with a surge in China's imports from the region appear
to be behind the recovery process, in spite of the slow down in the US,
which is the most important market for the region. However, the vulnerability
of the continued heavy dependence of these economies on externally-driven
growth is reflected in the fact that in 2003, East Asian output growth
is expected to be weaker than in 2002 (though faster than in Latin America),
with the SARS outbreak having an impact on earnings from trade and services.
In general, the findings on varying success in industrial catching-up
paths followed by the different developing countries have lead the TDR
to seriously question the strategies adopted by a range of developing
countries, which attempt to activate a dynamic process of capital accumulation
and growth through a combination of increased FDI and reduced public investment
and policy intervention.
The Report underscores the crucial role played by domestic entrepreneurs
in the process of capital accumulation in a late industrialising developing
country. This is based on the evidence that after the initial stages of
industrialisation, capital accumulation is financed primarily by profits
in the form of corporate retention, rather than household savings. While
the role played a domestic entrepreneur base is clearly crucial to a sustainable
industrialisation strategy, the explanation in the Report citing the linkage
between domestic capital formation and corporate profits fails to consider
the capital accumulation process in many large emerging market economies,
where household savings continue to play a prominent role.
Whatever the source of capital accumulation, what is important to note
is that in the countries that were able to generate sizeable resources
for investment, market forces alone were not left to dictate either its
pace or direction. TDR disputes the claims for the virtues of unlimited
competition in relation to economic development. The East Asian NIEs did
not have the maximum competition in product, capital or labour markets
(which the neoliberal paradigm propounds as basic to achieving efficient
growth), rather, they strived to achieve an optimal degree of cooperation
and competition. The defining features of successful development strategies
followed particularly by the first-tier NIEs were the following: a low-interest-rate
policy; using trade, financial and industrial policies to coordinate investment
decisions to prevent "investment races"; and long-term ties
between banks and large corporations.
It is known how many of these same institutional features which were recognised
to have contributed to the "Asian Miracle" came under misguided
criticism as the factors responsible for the financial crisis during 1997-98.
On the contrary, studies have clearly shown that a major reason for the
deterioration in the performance of such institutional arrangements in
East Asia, which had served them well until the phase of full-fledged
financial liberalization, was precisely the dismantling of the checks
and balances that had been part of the earlier system under the onslaught
of rapid integration into the world economy. In particular, this occurred
in two crucial areas: control over external borrowing; and state guidance
of private investment. TDR 2003 is therefore justifiably doubtful that
a "second generation" of neoliberal reforms will start to put
things back on track.
The Way Forward
In making these gloomy assessments about the prospects for a strong economic
recovery, the Report takes into account the prospects for acceleration
in financial flows and trade to developing countries, as well as the potential
for international currency realignments. The Report emphasises that sustainable
expansion of trade and capital flows now depends on a rapid recovery of
the world economy, rather than the other way around as the proponents
of further trade and financial liberalisation argue.
It is observed that while economic recovery in the developed countries
has failed to pick up strongly, growth in international trade, which had
decelerated subsequent to the IT bubble burst and the global economic
slowdown since 2000, registered only a modest recovery in 2002. While
factors such as greater trade liberalisation, deeper vertical integration
(through increased spread of international production networks) and increased
capital inflows can once again enable international trade to expand faster
than global production and income, all these factors are currently operating
under strict limits due to sluggish growth and rising unemployment globally.
Net private capital flows to developing countries also rebound in 2002,
reversing the steady decline since 1996. However, given that the surge
in financial flows in the 1990s was also largely due to one-off policy
changes related to the deregulation of national financial markets and
liberalisation of international financial flows, the Report cautions against
excessive optimism for an increase in capital flows to the levels seen
in the nineties. Further, with the evidence showing that most greenfield
FDI is also attracted by growth and not vice versa, it is anticipated
that the partial recovery in flows seen last year is unlikely to herald
a stronger upturn in inflows.
According to the TDR, the exchange rate adjustments that are now occurring
are also unlikely to reduce global trade imbalances and therefore, unlikely
to support global recovery. This is because, since a large proportion
of the US trade deficit is with the East Asian countries, a correction
of these imbalances would require the dollar to depreciate against the
East Asian currencies, including the yen. But, there are varying pressures
acting upon the latter nations, which may make this difficult to materialize.
These include Japan's reliance on export growth as the only source of
demand expansion and the intense export competition among the East Asian
developing countries.
In the absence of effective currency alignments and rapid growth in Europe
and Japan, the external adjustment required to break this global deadlock,
this then calls for a faster price deflation in the US than in the former
economies. Thus, the Report argues that global growth will continue to
depend heavily on the performance of the US economy and its policy choices.
But, based on the US economy's performance during the past three years,
decisive action would be needed in order to avert the danger of a prolonged
deflation in the US. While the US monetary authorities have shown readiness
to fight deflation by injecting money into the economy in order to induce
price rises, much of the task, according to the TDR, will fall on fiscal
policy. This calls for a reorientation of US public spending in order
to increase investments in areas such as public infrastructure, health
and environment.
However, given that there is a global deflationary situation, the Report
calls for bold Keynesian type of globally coordinated expansionary action,
so as to stabilize the international monetary and financial system. Only
coordinated monetary policies can help in bringing about stability to
capital flows, and an orderly realignment of exchange rates. However,
clearly, given that there is now a real danger of the emergence of a "liquidity
trap" in economies that are considered to be engines of growth, monetary
policy might become ineffective in checking and reversing the falls in
output and employment, unless it is combined with coordinated fiscal expansion
to expand liquidity and effective demand, both at the national and global
levels.
In the case of developing countries too, TDR makes bold suggestions as
to how to escape from the vicious circle of low and unstable growth, high
interest rates and rising indebtedness. For example, the Report emphasizes
less dependence on foreign capital and greater efforts to build stronger
investment-export linkages to ease the BOP constraint. It also suggests
that ways must be found to improve the contribution of FDI to these goals.
Further, it calls for more strategic policies to support higher investment
and upgrading, and active policies in the areas of industrial support,
technological progress and public infrastructure.
But, it is by now well acknowledged that several agreements under the
WTO combined together taken in letter and spirit, as well as the several
conditionalities attached to various debt relief and financial assistance
programmes from international financial institutions (IFIs) and donor
countries mean that developing countries have very little policy space
in effect. But, very often, official publications from international organisations
fail to discuss the actual policy flexibility which remains for various
countries, for pursuing the kind of interventionist development policies
which they advocate.
The TDR has also been disappointing in this regard. The Report makes
a passing mention of the failure of Cancun and of the WTO to deliver on
its development promises, the lack of progress of international financial
reform and in developing countries' participation in decision-making in
the Bretton Woods institutions and the WTO. But, it totally ignores a
discussion of how the policies suggested by them can be practised. The
Report fails to acknowledge just how difficult it is for late industrialisers
today to adopt some of the most important policy tools that were so crucial
to the industrial development strategies of earlier generation industrializers
in achieving the above goals.
Several prominent works from the UN organisations themselves have lucidly
established the glaring problems faced by developing countries in the
context of WTO agreements and implementation. There is a need to incorporate
the essence of these works into official publications, for the maximisation
of the existing provisions in the WTO for policy flexibility for developing
countries, and to call for reformulations wherever necessary, in order
to make the global system more fair, and thus, more sustainable for both
developing and the developed countries. Probably, the next natural step
for TDR should be to plunge deeper into the implications of the trade
agreements that have been carried out at various levels by developing
countries. There is also a critical need for incorporating indepth analysis
of service sector industries as well into analyses of capital accumulation
and structural change.
Further, the focus of TDR 2003 appears to be on export-led growth as
the single most important development strategy choice facing developing
countries. Given the fact that this has only led to increased dependence
of their economies on external demand and external capital and consequent
cycles of boom and bust (as the Report itself shows so decisively), it
would have added further value if the Report had explored beyond the framework
of export-led growth to the need for varying development strategies based
on the relevance of the domestic economy in the context of the distinctions
between small and large economies, and the need for domestically-pegged
growth even in the context of export-oriented growth strategies.
Overall, TDR 2003 has definitely added weight to the growing volume of
dissenting analyses on market-driven globalisation. Unfortunately, the
tragedy of the times is that such incisive assessments and analyses brought
forth by the UNCTAD, however, fails to instigate similar soul-searching
by developed country policy makers, IFIs, and other multilateral organisations
such as the WTO. Even in the face of mounting evidence suggesting severe
lacunae in their prescriptions, the latter continue to seek refuge behind
ideological fixations and a plethora of yet more development-friendly
phrases and policy papers.
December 23, 2003.
December 23, 2003.
|