Again
we are witnessing a hunger crisis in Africa. We should
give all the help we can, but we should also ask ourselves
one basic question: why does famine occur only in
those countries that are specialized in agriculture?
It is indeed a paradox: to a nation having a high
percentage of population engaged in agriculture signifies
a high risk of famine. Why is it that countries where
only a tiny percentage of the population make their
living producing food - like Europe and the USA -in
fact produce so much more than they consume that they
dump excess production on the world markets?
This is the nature of The Paradox of Famine, a phenomenon
that has been observed for a long time and for which
the economics profession used to have remedies. Diversification
of the economy away from agriculture is, paradoxically,
a key to preventing hunger. By moving hands from agriculture
into other activities, into 'mechanic industry', as
the author of an anonymous 1690 pamphlet puts it:
'That mechanics prevent famine in a nation; that this
at first sight will appear a paradox, that the multiplying
of mouths that eat corn, whose hands sow none, should
yet increase food; which matter of fact demonstrates
the truth of, notwithstanding: For whoever saw a famine
in Holland? On the contrary, they who sow none, yet
supply other parts of the world with corn, which they
effect by means of their arts and trade, which drives
the more profitable plough of the two, that of the
sea'.
Another question related to the Famine Paradox is
this: why do the most efficient farmers of the world
- those in Europe and the US - need heavy subsidies
in order to have a decent income? Why is the annual
subsidy per cow in the US and EU higher than the annual
income of many African farmers? Are the politicians
in the rich countries victims of extortion from their
own farmers, or is there an alternative explanation?
The basic answer to the Famine Paradox is that agricultural
production answers to different economic laws than
the industrial and advanced service sectors. Agriculture
will, after a point, be subject to diminishing returns,
it produces very few synergies (linkages), and is
generally subject to perfect competition. The first
economist who understood this well was Antonio Serra
who, in 1613, explained the wealth of Venice and the
poverty of Naples and whose Brief Treatise for the
first time was published in English this month (London,
Anthem Press).
Since then European and later US industrialization
was based on this same understanding. Increasing returns,
technological change, imperfect competition, and synergies
'collude' to raise wages in industrialized nations,
and the high cost of labor induces technical change
in their agricultural sector. Although the US had
an absolute advantage in agriculture over Europe,
the nation still wisely decided to industrialize.
Sporadic famines in Europe contributed to convincing
nations of the need to industrialize. The 1846 failure
of the wheat and rye harvests across Europe no doubt
contributed - with the massive financial crisis of
1847 - both to the revolutionary fervor building up
to the revolutions of 1848 and to a better understanding
of the need to industrialize and to the postponing
of free trade until after industrialization.
The European reconstruction after WW II and classical
development economics were based on this very same
principle: a nation specializing in agriculturewill
specialize according to its comparative advantage
in being poor. This does not mean that an industrialized
country cannot live from exporting agricultural products.
In synthesis: although famines also have political
elements, history unanimously shows that only countries
with a manufacturing sector have managed to free themselves
from famines. Such a strategy requires active policies
that go against the present principles of the WTO.
Famines can of course also be avoided in countries
with a huge petroleum-sector rent. But, feeding the
people from petroleum rents rather than from a diversified
local production is, in the long run, not a sustainable
strategy.
Our 17th century anonymous author also dwells on Christian
charity towards the poor. He suggests, however, that
the real solution to poverty and famine does not lie
in charity but in Christian compassion by preventing
this situation from happening in the first place.
This is still true: the only real solution to hunger
is still to diversify the economies of famine-stricken
countries.
August
03, 2011.
|