Suddenly,
discussions about economic growth and how to generate
it are back in fashion among economists. Ironically,
this renewed interest comes about just as the recent
global economic boom is petering out, when the immediate
prospects for the international economy are not of
sustained growth but of stagflation.
There was a period of around two decades, from the
mid 1980s onwards, when how to kick-start economic
growth was not recognised as a relevant question.
The focus was not on growth per se but on stabilisation
and “efficiency”. It was taken for granted
by mainstream neo-classical economists and the policy
makers influenced by them that economic growth would
come about on its own, once markets were deregulated
and rules for domestic and international trade and
investment were liberalised. In this story, growth
was something best left to market determination freed
from “the dead hand of the state” and
unfettered by government failures, which would make
the resulting economic expansion both more efficient
and more dynamic.
Much of the empirical debate around globalisation
also somehow ended up in this simplistic paradigmatic
framework, even though the processes of globalisation
were not essentially about “free” and
competitive markets so much as about new trajectories
for corporate capital and changed bargaining relations
between capital on the one hand and workers and peasants
on the other.
But the reality of the past two decades has been chastening,
as the promised growth did not materialise in many
countries that wholeheartedly embraced these principles,
and the most dynamic economies turned out to be those
with much more flexible and heterodox approaches to
economic policy. So economic growth moved from being
the obvious result of “good policies”,
to becoming the subject of the newest growth industry
inside the economics profession.
Economists have begun, even if very belatedly and
without much enthusiasm, to interrogate their prior
suppositions. We now have a spate of academic books
and reports of international organisations, rediscovering
basic truths of development economics that were not
so much forgotten as actively suppressed and covered
up.
Thus in 2005, the World Bank, previously the leader
of the pack espousing free market principles as the
inevitable formula for all economic contexts and requirements,
came up with a volume entitled “Economic growth
in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform”.
In this, a bunch of World Bank economists examined
growth patterns and thereby suddenly “discovered”
what many others could have told them all along if
only they had cared to listen. Consider some of the
insights that they have come up with:
- It is overly naïve to expect that simply
reducing tariffs or liberalising finance will automatically
increase growth
- Stabilisation and macroeconomic management need
to be growth-oriented.
- Governments need to be made accountable, not
bypassed.
- Governments should abandon formulaic policymaking.
Of course, it is nice to know that at least some
people in the World Bank have now realised all this,
and we should no doubt welcome their entry into the
real world. But it is startling, if not downright
appalling, to think of how much suffering and undue
economic pain has been inflicted upon people across
the developing world because these rather obvious
points were simply not accepted for all these years.
As a result, there was nothing to mitigate the dogmatic
and relentless pressure that was applied to developing
country policy makers, not only by the World Bank
but by international finance and the prevailing mainstream
“consensus”. The resulting policies created
patterns of production and specialisation that destroyed
existing livelihoods without generating enough new
employment, did not allow enough public investment
in physical and social infrastructure to sustain future
growth, and reduced the access of the poor to basic
goods and services, including food, sanitation, health
and education. These conditions and processes are
not easily reversed, so that the suffering will continue
for some time even if the economic policies are changed
now. After all this, to come up with a volume that
effectively says “Sorry, we got it wrong”
is more than mildly outrageous.
The latest such offering from the international establishment
is the Report of the high-profile Commission on Growth
and Development. This Commission, with a secretariat
based in the World Bank, consisted of 21 “world
leaders and experts” that was chaired by Nobel
Prize-winning economist Michael Spence, and included
inter alia Montek Singh Ahluwahlia from India. With
its estimated budget of more than $4 million, for
more than two years this Commission held meetings
and workshops, consulted with about 200 economists,
commissioned around 80 research papers, all to “unravel
the mystery of economic growth”.
The resulting Report has been criticised for saying
little more than what undergraduate students in economics
could come up with. But it is significant in that
market fundamentalism, which would probably have characterised
such a Report even recently, is replaced by a genuine
acceptance of ignorance and acceptance of past mistakes
in declarations about growth. The Report admits that
“orthodoxies apply only so far.”
The Report identifies 13 economies that are described
as “high growth” because they have grown
at an average rate of 7 per cent a year or more for
25 years or longer: Botswana, Brazil, China, Hong
Kong, Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, Malta,
Oman, Singapore, Taiwan Province of China and Thailand.
On the basis of these “success stories”
they build a story of the likely elements that generate
such a sustained growth process.
So, in the Growth Commission Report, the elements
for success are as follows:
- investment of at least 25 per cent of gross domestic
product, predominantly financed by domestic savings,
including investment of some 5-7 per cent of GDP
in infrastructure;
- spending by private and public sectors of another
7-8 per cent of GDP on education, training and health;
- inward technology transfer, facilitated by exploitation
of opportunities for trade and inward foreign direct
investment;
- acceptance of competition, structural change
and urbanisation;
- competitive labour markets, at least at the margin;
- the need to bring environmental protection into
development from the beginning;
- equality of opportunity, particularly for women.
Similarly, the Report provides a list of policies
to be avoided if sustained high growth is to be achieved:
- subsidising energy;
- using the civil service as employer of last resort;
- reducing fiscal deficits by cutting spending
on infrastructure;
- providing open-ended protection to specific sectors;
- using price controls as a way to curb inflation;
- banning exports, to keep domestic prices low;
- under-investing in urban infrastructure;
- underpaying public servants, such as teachers;
- allowing the exchange rate to appreciate too
far, too quickly.
Even with all the caveats, there is much that is
simplistic and over-generalising in these recommendations.
To start with, of course, the basic presumption that
growth will necessarily lead to improved economic
conditions of the majority of the population is questionable,
as is tentatively noted in an early chapter. The example
of the African success story Botswana testifies amply
to this, since its spectacular growth has been accompanied
by poverty rates that persist at more than half of
the population, falling life expectancy and sharply
worsening income distribution.
Even if growth per se is uncritically accepted to
be the goal, each of these positive and negative conditions
can be questioned and counter examples can be provided.
The Report does accept that it cannot provide a formula
for policy makers to apply, since no generic formula
exists. But aside from some obvious points (such as
the need for high investment rates, especially in
infrastructure) most of the other points can be contested.
For example, while bringing in environmental protection
into the development process from the start is undoubtedly
a good thing and should be encouraged anyway, none
of the successful examples quoted by the Commission
has actually practised it. With respect to the policies
to be avoided, one or other of these has been practised
at different times by several of the success stories,
often precisely during their “high growth”
phase. Conversely, many low or even negative growth
countries (such as Zambia, Ghana, Nicaragua, Bolivia)
have followed many or most of these prescriptions,
but with the opposite of success because they have
been combined with other market-oriented policies
that have completely undermined any possibility of
growth.
So it is also interesting to read what the Commission
does not say, since that reflects – finally!
– a minimum recognition of reality. Crucially,
there is no mention of financial liberalisation as
a necessary condition for growth. Nor is there a blanket
recommendation for trade and investment liberalisation:
exploiting opportunities for trade and foreign direct
investment can be done as much and probably more effectively
under highly regulated circumstances, as in China.
The Report’s silence is deafening on the Washington
Consensus conditions for growth such as “prudent”
macroeconomic policies and fiscal discipline, which
it barely mentions. It even says that it is bad to
reduce fiscal deficits by cutting public infrastructure
spending!
So what does one make of all this “new”
knowledge? The central point – and one that
our policy makers would do well to remember –
is that the orthodox set of stabilisation and liberalisation
policies to which we were told that “there is
no alternative” are not only not sufficient,
but can even be counterproductive in terms of generating
growth.
This conclusion may not be particularly novel to many
observers, but remember that this was a Commission
of largely mainstream thinkers. It may have avoided
the question of what pattern of growth is really desirable
for most people, but that it was prepared to go even
this far in questioning standard beliefs is some indication
of how much the economics mainstream itself is shifting.
August 11, 2008.
|