On
July 29, a meeting of ministerial representatives
of a large group of members of the World Trade Organisation
ended without result. The meeting itself should not
have been held in the first place. It was unscheduled,
and was convened to clinch a deal on the modalities
that should govern the Doha Round of trade negotiations,
even though there was no evidence that members were
anywhere near agreement in a number of areas that
mattered. Ministerials work when countries are near
agreement. However, with the terms of the Bush administration
and of the WTO Director General Pascal Lamy nearing
their end, it was widely believed that the Doha Round,
which would have to wait for new leaders with different
priorities, would be delayed significantly. Powerful
forces were therefore at work to push through a quick
deal. What is surprising is that for a little while
it appeared that Pascal Lamy, acting on their behalf,
may actually succeed.
All that said, the collapse of the talks is no big
deal for those working towards an agreement. For years
now, an ever increasing number of WTO member countries
have at all times being negotiating one or other round
of a multilateral trade agreement. These talks move
in peculiar stop-go fashion with gradually increasing
areas of agreement. When some critical quantum of
advance relative to the previous round is realised,
a formal agreement is signed and talks on the remaining
issues postponed for the future. Along this traverse,
periodic failure of negotiations involving representatives
at various levels of government is inevitable. However,
each time, the effort to avoid failure results in
some compromise so that even if the talks fail at
that stage, the round itself has "progressed".
This is true of this episode of failure as well, with
some progress on issues such as the trade in bananas
and duty-free exports to industrial markets for the
poorest countries.
The collapse is not a disaster for advocates of trade
liberalisation also because the postponement of a
"final" agreement in this round of talks
does not mean that the actual degree of liberalisation
of global trade would be far less than would have
been the case if the deal had been clinched. This
is because the deal is not all about reducing the
actual extent of protection in global trade, but more
about legally fixing the maximum degree and the form
of protection that a country can resort to in different
areas. The actual degree of protection in most cases
is way below this "binding" level, because
while multilateral trade talks are underway, countries
either unilaterally or through bilateral and regional
agreements have been liberalising their trade regime
far more than required by the maximum protection they
are legally committed to or are committing themselves
to at the WTO.
The point to note is that the so-called progress in
trade liberalisation notwithstanding, the fundamental
asymmetry of the world trading system remains. It
is reflected, on the one hand, in the protection afforded
by the huge subsidies paid out by the US and the EU
to their agricultural sectors and the non-tariff barriers
periodically resorted to by them in other sectors
where their competitiveness is under challenge. On
the other, it is seen in the pressure on the developing
countries to open up their markets for manufacturing
by relaxing regulations relating to Non-Agricultural
Market Access (NAMA) and subjecting their farming
sector to competition from imports, even though agriculture
is a far more important source of livelihood in these
countries than is the protected agricultural sector
for the developed economies.
This feature of the system makes it difficult to keep
developing countries at the table in the ever on-going
negotiations. Many strategies have been adopted for
the purpose. The asymmetry has been sought to be concealed.
Inequality in power relations between the developed
and the developing has been used to "cajole"
the developing countries into being part of the process.
Differences between developing countries with varying
levels of development and differing economic characteristics
are used to force them to negotiate, by pitting one
group of developing countries against another. Finally,
in a move to sidestep the demand that arose in the
wake of the Uruguay Round that issues arising from
the implementation of that agreement, including the
non-realisation of benefits promised to the developing
countries, should be considered first before launching
on a new round, the developed countries agreed to
declare the round that was indeed launched at Doha
a Development Round.
The duplicity implicit in all this is visible in recent
developments as well. To lend credibility to his decision
to call for an unscheduled ministerial meet to push
through an agreement, Pascal Lamy released drafts
of agreements, with significant sections left bracketed
or incomplete, in two contentious areas—agriculture
and non-agricultural market access. These drafts had
all elements that reproduce the asymmetry in trade
relations.
Consider agriculture for example. There are two means
through which support for agriculture in the developed
countries is sustained through the ongoing process
of make-believe liberalisation. The first is to maintain
the focus on Overall Trade-Distorting Domestic Support
(OTDS), with reductions in maximum possible support
always kept above the actual level of support provided.
The second is to shift the structure of support in
favour of the so-called "Green Box" provisions
that constitute permissible support.
In the many "concessions" offered by the
US and Europe in the run up to the July ministerial,
they promised to reduce the permissible OTDS by 70
and 80 per cent respectively. In the case of the US,
this would have meant that the currently permitted
OTDS of $48 billion would be reduced to $14.5 billion.
What needs to be noted however is that at the prevailing
agricultural prices, which influence the levels of
support provided to farmers, the actual or applied
OTDS level in the US stood at $ 7 billion in 1996-97,
rose to $19 billion in 2005 and fell to $11 billion
in 2006 and $8 billion in 2007. Rarely has the US
had to give its heavily subsidised farmers even the
$14. 5 billion it can provide if its current offer
is included in an agreement.
In the case of the EU, the currently permitted OTDS
of Euro 110 billion was slated to fall to Euro 22
billion. This compares with an estimated actual support
of Euro 28 billion in 2008 and Euro 12 billion by
the time the ongoing reform of the Common Agricultural
Policy is completed in 2014. Here too, what is on
offer is a ceiling on OTDS that is way above what
the EU intends to actually provide its farmers in
the coming years. In any case, all this relates to
what is considered "trade-distorting" support.
Over time the developed countries have shifted their
support to farmers away from what are considered trade-distorting
measures in favour of payments ostensibly "decoupled"
from production and therefore considered non-trade
distorting. The demand that these payments should
be investigated and the huge support provided in the
form of Green Box payments made more transparent and
trimmed has not been accepted.
The real intent of the US at least comes through from
the Farm Bill voted into law by the US Congress on
May 22, a few weeks before the July ministerial. The
bill authorizes spending of up to $307 billion over
five fiscal years starting October 1, 2008, a significant
part of which is available as to support farmers.
As an analysis of the Bill by the Institute for Agricultural
Trade and Policy put it: "Nothing in the 2008
legislation changes the basic structure of U.S. support,
which will rise and fall in reaction to world prices.
And the WTO rules are also fundamentally unchanged
by the Doha proposals. These latest developments are
yet another reminder of the urgent need to re-think
agriculture trade policy, both in the U.S. and around
the world."
Meanwhile, the developing countries which expected
significant concessions for their agricultural sectors
in the form of "special products" and "special
safeguard mechanisms" (SSMs) are being pressured
into reducing their right to protect their farming
sector when circumstances require. In the agriculture
draft, tariffs above 130 per cent are required to
be cut by between 44 and 49 per cent and those below
30 per cent by 33 per cent, with cuts within that
range for duties that currently rule at between 30
and 130 per cent. This takes the average tariff cut
for developing country agriculture to 36 per cent,
which is much higher than what was required under
the Uruguay Round.
Further, special concessions have been limited significantly.
Special products are those which are important from
the point of view of food security and farmers' livelihoods,
and developing countries originally wanted the right
to self-designate up to 20 per cent of tariff lines
under this category. These commodities would receive
higher protection, with no tariff reduction commitments
required in at least half of them and the rest requiring
at most minimal tariff cuts.
The Lamy draft has substantially trimmed the concession
that would be available under this head. It specifies
that only 12 per cent of tariff lines can be special
products, with 5 per cent permitted zero tariff reduction,
subject to the requirement that group as a whole will
be subject to an average tariff reduction of 11per
cent. This implies that if a country chooses 5 per
cent of tariff lines where the duty reduction is zero,
duty rates in the other 7 per cent of tariff lines
have to be cut by 19 per cent, so as to realise the
average cut of 11per cent for the 12 per cent of tariff
lines designated as SPs.
The issue which is supposed to have broken this round
of talks was reportedly the SSMs, or safeguards against
a sudden surge in imports. If imports of a product
exceeds some 10 per cent or more of the average imports
over the previous three years, the mechanism allows
developing countries to raise tariffs by differing
degrees depending on the size of the surge. The difficulty
would be that this may require the country to impose
a tariff in excess of the maximum (bound) rate of
tariff permitted under its commitments under the Uruguay
Round. Negotiations around the Lamy draft led to the
demand that developing countries should do this only
if imports equal or exceed 40 per cent of average
imports during the three preceding years. Developing
countries including India and China objected to this
on the ground that a 40 per cent import surge would
be adequate to destroy the livelihoods of a large
number of farmers. Acting then would not serve the
purpose the SSM is to be set up for. The US and other
developed countries claim that the refusal of China
and India to climb down on this issue broke the talks.
There are many who think this was too small an issue
to explain the collapse and there were many other
issues, including the subsidies provided by the US
to its cotton growers with adverse consequences for
African exports, which were far more contentious.
In their view, the US chose to use this issue to sabotage
the talks before it was forced to declare its position
in areas like cotton that had been kept for a later
stage in the talks.
That is, SSMs were chosen as the deal breaker because
they involved disagreement with countries like China
and India which are seen as not deserving too much
by way of special concessions given their high growth
in recent years. On the other hand, the US was saved
the embarrassment of not offering adequate concessions
to the much poorer African developing countries. The
fact of the matter is that there were a large number
of developing countries who were behind China and
India on this issue.
But India and China are themselves partly responsible
for being the target of attack. They were susceptible
to an attack of this kind because they, along with
Brazil, decided to negotiate separately with the US
and EU, acting ostensibly on behalf of other developing
countries. According to reports, although some 40
ministers were invited to the talks, most of the negotiations
were conducted by only seven ministers (from the United
States, European Commission, India, Brazil, China,
Australia and Japan), besides Pascal Lamy himself.
In practice the other developing countries had no
idea of how and where the talks were heading. This
desire to cut a deal with the developed by distancing
themselves from the other developing countries, besides
contributing to the undemocratic nature of trade negotiations,
makes these countries culpable when it comes to accounting
for the inequality of the multilateral trading system.
August 7, 2008. |