China
and India seem to be the hot topics in the world economy
today. In the international press, there is almost
an obsession with these two economies, and how their
current growth presages the coming "Asian century".
It is not just that they are both countries with large
populations covering substantial and diverse geographical
areas, and therefore with huge potential economic
size. Most of all, they are cited as the current "success
stories": two economies in the developing world
that have apparently benefited from globalisation,
with relatively high and stable rates of growth for
more than two decades and substantial diversification.
In India too, the obsession with China is now well-developed,
mostly in the form of a longing eastern gaze. The
rapid economic growth and structural transformation
in China are not just eyed with envy; they are typically
invoked to justify the economic policy of choice.
Thus there are those who argue that the recent Chinese
economic success is because of liberalisation and
openness to foreign trade and investment. By contrast,
others point out that the early Communist history
of land reforms and egalitarian policies formed the
essential basis upon which all subsequent change has
depended.
In the outside literature, these economies are often
treated as broadly similar in terms of growth potential
and other features, and this even infects some Indian
analyses. But in fact there are crucial differences
between the two economies which render such similarities
very superficial, and which mean that individual policies
cannot be taken out of context of one country and
simply applied in the other to the same effect. There
are at least ten significant differences.
The first relates to the nature of the economy itself,
the institutional conditions within which policies
are formulated and implemented. India could be described
until recently as a traditional "mixed economy"
with a large private sector, so it was and remains
a capitalist market economy with the associated tendency
to involuntary unemployment. So the need for macroeconomic
policies to stimulate demand, as common in capitalist
economies, operated in addition to the usual “developmental”
role of the state.
China, by contrast, has been for the most part a command
economy, which until recently had a very small private
sector, and only recognised the legal possibility
of home-grown capitalists a few years ago. Throughout
the period of "liberalisation", that is
the 1990s and later, there have remained important
forms of state control over macroeconomic processes
that have differed from more conventional capitalist
macroeconomic policy. Even in 2004, public enterprises
accounted for more than half of GDP and more than
two-fifths of exports.
The control over the domestic economic in China has
been most significant in terms of the financial sector,
which describes the second big difference between
the two economies. In India, the financial sector
was typical of the "mixed economy" and even
bank nationalisation did not lead to comprehensive
government control over the financial system; in any
case, financial liberalisation over the 1990s has
involved a progressive deregulation and further loss
of control over financial allocations by the state
in India.
But the financial system in China still remains heavily
under the control of the state, despite recent liberalisation.
Four major public sector banks handle the bulk of
the transactions in the economy, and the Chinese authorities
have essentially used control over the consequent
financial flows to regulate the volume of credit (and
therefore mange the economic cycle) as well as to
direct credit to priority sectors. Off-budget official
finance (called "fund-raising" by firms)
has accounted for more than half of capital formation
in China even in recent years, and that together with
direct budgetary appropriations have determined nearly
two thirds of the level of aggregate investment. This
means that there has been less need for more conventional
fiscal and monetary policies, although the Chinese
economy is now in the process of transition to the
more standard pattern.
The third difference is quite apparent to all – the
dramatically high rate of GDP growth in China compared
to the more moderate expansion in India. The Chinese
economy has grown at an average annual rate of 9.8
per cent for two and a half decades, while India’s
economy has grown at around 5-6 per cent per year
over the same period. Chinese growth has been relatively
volatile around this trend, reflecting stop-go cycles
of state response to inflation through aggregate credit
management.
This higher growth in China essentially occurs because
of the fourth major difference, the much higher rate
of investment in China. The investment rate in China
(investment as a share of GDP) has fluctuated between
35 and 44 per cent over the past 25 years, compared
to 20 to 26 per cent in India. In fact, the aggregate
ICORs (incremental capital-output ratios) have been
around the same in both economies. Within this, there
is the critical role of infrastructure investment,
which has averaged at 19 of GDP in China compared
to 2 per cent in India over the 1990s.
It is sometimes argued that China can afford to have
such a high investment rate because it has attracted
so much foreign direct investment (FDI), and is the
second largest recipient of FDI in the world at present.
But FDI has accounted for only 3-5 per cent of GDP
in China since 1990, and at its peak was still only
8 per cent. In recent times, the inflow of capital
has not added to the domestic investment rate at all,
but to the holding of international reserves, which
have increased by $100 billion per year.
In terms of economic diversification and structural
change, China has followed what could be described
as the classic industrialisation pattern, moving from
primary to manufacturing activities in the past 25
years. The manufacturing sector has doubled its share
of workforce and tripled its share of output, which,
given the size of the Chinese economy and population,
has increasingly made China "the workshop of
the world". In India, by contrast, the move has
been mainly from agriculture to services in the share
of output, with no substantial increase in manufacturing,
and the structure of employment has been stubbornly
resistant to change. The recent expansion of some
services employment in India has been at both high
and low value added ends of the services sub-sectors,
reflecting both some dynamism and some increase in
"refuge" low productivity employment.
The sixth major difference relate to trade policy
and trade patterns. Chinese export growth has been
much more rapid, involving aggressive increases on
world market shares. This export growth has been based
on relocative capital which has been attracted not
only by cheap labour but also by excellent and heavily
subsidised infrastructure resulting from the high
rate of infrastructure investment. In addition, since
the Chinese state has also been keen on provision
of basic goods in terms of housing, food and cheap
transport facilities, this has played an important
role in reducing labour costs for employers. In India,
the cheap labour has been because of low absolute
wages rather than public provision and underwriting
of labour costs, and infrastructure development has
been minimal. So it is not surprising that it has
not really been an attractive location for export-oriented
investment, its rate of export growth has been much
lower, and exports have not become an engine of growth.
There is another issue relating to trade policy. In
China, the rapid export growth generated employment
which was a net addition to domestic employment, since
until 2002 China had undertaken much less trade liberalisation
than most other developing countries. This is why
manufacturing employment grew so rapidly in China,
because it was not counterbalanced by any loss of
employment through the effects of displacement of
domestic industry because of import competition. This
is unlike the case in India, where increases in export
employment were outweighed by employment losses especially
in small enterprises because of import competition.
The seventh difference is in terms of poverty reduction.
China has been much more successful in this regard
– official data suggest that 4 per cent of the population
now lives under the poverty line, unofficial estimates
suggest around 12 per cent. The poverty ratio in India
is much higher, between 26 per cent and 34 per cent
according to the 1999-2000 NSS data. The Chinese success
in this regard can be related to several features:
to begin with, the basic issues in terms of asset
redistribution and basic needs provision were the
focus of the Communist state until the late 1970s.
This also assisted in economic growth: because of
the more egalitarian system, there was a larger mass
market for consumption goods, which has allowed producers
to take advantage of economies of scale.
Subsequently, poverty reduction in China has been
concentrated into two main phases: 1979-82 and 1994-96,
which were both phases of higher crop prices and rising
agricultural incomes. In the first phase, institutional
change in the form of allowing peasant production
in diversified crops played a great role in increasing
productivity and allowing peasants to benefit from
rising prices. Also, since Chinese economic growth
has been more employment generating, this has also
operated to reduce poverty.
Until recently, there was much more focus on "human
development" in China, and public provision of
health and education. This included universal education
until Class X, as well as better public services to
ensure nutrition, health and sanitation. However,
in recent years, this emphasis has been much reduced
and there is greater privatisation of such services
in China, which has also led to worsening conditions
especially in particular areas. In India, the public
provision of all of these has been extremely inadequate
throughout this period and has deteriorated in per
capita terms since the early 1990s.
In terms of inequality, in both economies, the recent
pattern of growth has been inequalising. In China,
the spatial inequalities – across regions – have been
the sharpest. In India, vertical inequalities and
the rural-urban divide have become much more marked.
In China recently, as a response to this, there have
been some top-down measures to reduce inequality,
for example through changes in tax rates, greater
public investment in western and interior regions,
and improved social security benefits. In India, it
is political change that has forced greater attention
to redressing inequalities, though the process is
still very incipient.
This brings into focus the tenth big difference: that
of political systems. It can be argued that the political
democracy in India, which now appears deeply entrenched
even though it has not translated into universal economic
enfranchisement, has played some role in creating
more confused but less extreme patterns of economic
growth. Certainly, historic and potentially transformatory
economic legislation such as the Employment Guarantee
Act could only come about because of impact of political
changes. Perhaps the ability of the political system
to force at least some change of direction in economic
policies in India can serve as an important example
to the rest of the world, and one of which Indians
can justly be proud.
However, in terms of the future prospects, surprisingly
both economies end up with very similar issues despite
these major differences. There are clear questions
of sustainability of the current pattern of economic
expansion in China, based on a high export-high accumulation
model which requires constantly increasing shares
of world markets and very high investment rates. Similarly,
the hope in some policy quarters in India that IT-enabled
services can become the engine of growth is one which
raises questions of sustainability.
The most important problems in the two economies are
also rather similar – the agrarian crisis and the
need to generate more employment. In both economies,
the social sectors have been neglected recently by
public intervention. In both countries, the policy
message appears to be the same, that the most basic
issues are those that require to be addressed first,
and if so the other areas of expansion will probably
look after themselves.
August 25, 2005.
|