A new
orthodoxy has taken root in the international discourse
on trade. According to this orthodoxy, if the advanced
economies cut import duties, remove non-tariff barriers
such as quotas or standards and stop protecting uncompetitive
domestic producers, then there will be a phenomenal
increase in the exports of the developing countries.
When accompanied by trade liberalisation in the developing
countries, the result will be a sea change in the
size and structure of the exports of their economies.
A couple of years ago, the World Bank, which was the
first international institution to articulate this
argument, projected that such changes would, by 2015,
see the developing countries increase their incomes
by $1.5 trillion and 320 million people would climb
out of poverty.
The new orthodoxy is sophisticated in that it turns
the spotlight on the unfair practices of the advanced
economies and calls for a change in the "rigged"
rules of world trade. This is quite different from
the earlier approach of the international institutions,
which had as its premise autonomous trade liberalisation
by the developing countries. More sophisticated the
new arguments may be, but how valid are they? The
answer is best provided by an assessment of what will
happen to the agricultural exports of the developing
economies. The new orthodoxy sees enormous benefits
for the poor countries if the barriers in the world
markets to their exports of manufactures, services
and agricultural products are removed. But the barriers
are most evident in agriculture and it is this sector
that is expected to yield the largest gains from the
creation of a more fair and transparent policy regime
in the advanced economies, in particular in the European
Union, Japan and the United States. The striking comparisons
offered in the 2003 edition of the UNDP Human Development
Report illustrates the scale of farm subsidies in
the rich countries. The $2,700 of annual subsidy received
by every cow in Japan is nearly 2,000 times the $1.47
of aid Japan provides to each citizen of sub-Saharan
Africa. The U.S. provides an average of $3.1 million
of aid a day to the countries of sub-Saharan Africa
but it gives the daily equivalent of $10.7 million
as domestic support to its cotton growers. And the
$311 billion of agricultural subsidies that the OECD
countries provide annually to their farmers is six
times as much as the aid they give to all developing
countries.
The logic of the arguments for dismantling the regime
that protects agriculture in the E.U., Japan and the
U.S. is impeccable. The huge support for agriculture
in the advanced countries hurts developing countries
in two ways. It makes their farm exports uncompetitive
in the global market because it holds down world prices,
often below the cost of production. The second destructive
impact of the subsidies in the rich countries is that
they facilitate a flooding of developing country markets
with these products, in the process destroying domestic
agriculture. Lowering rich country subsidies will
aid developing country exports as well as restore
agricultural production in countries now hurt by subsidised
imports. But it would be a fair assessment to make
that cutting domestic support and lowering customs
duties on agriculture will not automatically benefit
the developing countries as a whole.
First, global agricultural prices are far more volatile
than industrial prices. So if the developing countries
are pushed to engage the world market in agriculture,
they will suffer all the ups and downs of this volatility.
They have in some respects already experienced the
negative effects of this volatility - in the
form of a steady decline in the prices of all primary
products since the 1980s. Of course, one can argue
that in the absence of a large subsidy to agriculture
in the advanced economies, world prices would not
have fallen as they did in the 1990s. This is true,
but it is also correct that whichever the agricultural
commodity - whether it is cereals or natural
raw materials - prices are always subject to
extreme fluctuations. The bigger and more efficient
countries can cope with this volatility, but not the
smaller ones. The effects of an engagement with the
world market will be doubly burdensome because the
price for getting the OECD countries to cut their
farm subsidies will be to reduce import duties on
agricultural products in the developing countries.
Second, agricultural productivity varies enormously
between the developing countries. So even if the subsidised
producers in the rich countries vacate the global
market, it will be the bigger and more productive
producers who will take their place. For example,
among the developed countries, Australia, Canada and
New Zealand will gain substantially in the markets
for cereals and dairy products. Among the middle-income
developing countries, Argentina, Brazil, Malaysia
and Thailand should benefit in cereals, meat and some
natural raw materials. Agricultural productivity in
all these countries is far higher than in most of
the developing world, so any hopes that the poorer
countries of Asia, Africa and South America will benefit
from agricultural trade liberalisation will quickly
be dashed.
The peculiarities in the global agricultural market
and the wide differences in productivity do not mean
that in all cases only a small group of countries
in the developing world will benefit from an end to
rich country subsidies to agriculture. In cotton,
there is the well known example of high productivity
and globally competitive production in west Africa
(mainly Burkina Faso, Chad and Mali) being squeezed
in the global market because of the $6 billion of
subsidies granted by the U.S., the E.U. and to a certain
extent China. Since cotton accounts for as much as
30 per cent of the exports of these countries and
contributes to 10 per cent of their national income,
they have much to gain if the subsidies in the developed
countries are slashed.
It is also not the case that just because the gains
from a dismantling of the subsidy regime in the rich
countries will accrue to only some countries, these
subsidy regimes should be left as they are. For decades,
the developed countries have used their financial
resources to prop up their agriculture and keep out
imports from the developing countries. At the same
time, they have pressured the poorer countries to
open their markets to industrial products. This hypocrisy
now stands exposed. But even as the developing countries
push for a winding down of the mammoth amounts of
domestic support that agriculture enjoys in the advanced
economies, they should have no illusions about using
agricultural exports as the route to prosperity.
India has decided, fortunately, not to buy the argument
that there is a pot of gold waiting for the country
if it is aggressive in demanding deep cuts in the
agricultural subsidy in the OECD countries. There
was earlier a strong body of opinion canvassing that
India join the Cairns group of farm exporters (Australia,
Canada, Brazil, Thailand, South Africa, New Zealand
and other major agricultural producers) who have been
pressing for both lower subsidies and import duties
in the E.U., the U.S., and Japan. If India had allied
with the Cairns group then it would be in the unhappy
position of not being able to provide even a modicum
of domestic support (because of the Government's resource
constraints) and yet having to agree to lower import
duties. This would have only made Indian agriculture
highly vulnerable to the swings in the global market.
There is nothing to suggest that Indian agricultural
exports are very competitive in the world market.
Exports of rice and wheat have gone up and down in
recent years, mainly because they have been offered
to exporters at subsidised prices. About the only
area where India could, in theory, have some chance
of making a major mark in the global market is fruits
and vegetables, of which the country is now the largest
producer. Here again, the expectations are based more
on hunches than a detailed analysis of where Indian
agriculture stands. It is more likely that Brazil,
Malaysia and South Africa will be able to offer better
prices than India. All told, India is better off not
taking an aggressive position on agriculture in the
Doha round of trade liberalisation talks at the WTO.
The risks are too high and the promised gains too
few to warrant a dramatic opening up of Indian agriculture
to foreign competition.
It is not that there is little to gain from demanding
lower subsidies and more open markets to agricultural
products in the advanced economies. These demands
have to be made. But lower subsidies and greater market
access in the developed countries do not offer a certain
route to a huge increase in agricultural exports by
the developing countries.
August 04, 2003.
|