On May 2, 1945, German General Weidling,
whom Hitler had entrusted with the defence of Berlin, surrendered unconditionally
to General Chuikov of the Red Army, bringing to an end the worst nightmare
in human history. The Third Reich, which was supposed to last a thousand
years, had collapsed amidst unprecedented ruin and loss of human life.
Today when we look back on that period, the question naturally arises:
how did it happen? Fritz Stern, scholar of German history, attributes
''Germany's descent from decency to Nazi barbarism'' to "a historic
process in which resentment against a disenchanted secular world found
deliverance in the ecstatic escape of unreason" (quoted in Noam Chomsky’s
''Remebering Fascism''). While Stern’s description is apposite, it misses
something vital, namely that the cause of the ''disenchantment'' and the
orchestrator of the ''unreason'' was the self-same entity, finance capital.
The ''disenchantment'' of the people with the economic fall-out of the
hegemony of finance capital, whose ambitions had pushed Germany into war
and broken its back with war reparations under the Treaty of Versailles,
even before the onset of the Great Depression, had given rise to fascism
as a mass movement. This mass movement, created around unreason but with
an anti-capitalist rhetoric, which identified capitalists with Jews, and
appealed both to the anti-semitism and the anti-big-capital sentiments
of the petty bourgeoisie, was then manipulated by the very same finance
capital into betraying itself. Fritz Thyssen, the ''great magnate of the
Ruhr'' financed Hitler’s elections and, together with other German monopolists,
made deals with the Nazi leadership, which, once it had come to power,
liquidated its own cadre of lumpens and hoodlums that had constituted
the backbone of its petty bourgeois mass movement.
In the ''night of long knives'', Ernst Rohm, the leader of the SA that
had carried Hitler to power, was executed and the entire SA leadership
was purged, so that the ''mass nature'' of fascism could not stand in
confrontation against its ''class nature''. The German army accepted the
symbol of the swastika, while Hitler took over the German army by eliminating
its rival, his own SA. A Nazi State came into being that represented at
the same time, in Dimitrov’s words, the ''open terrorist dictatorship
of the most reactionary and revanchist sections of finance capital''.
A petty bourgeois mass movement with anti-capitalist rhetoric had transmogrified
itself into an open terrorist dictatorship of finance capital.
This is not to say that the petty bourgeoisie deserted Hitler, but its
support was now obtained not on the basis of any anti-capitalist programme
of action but through appeals to its revanchist nationalism that the war
fanned. And with unemployment of the Depression overcome through the military
expenditure that swelled in preparation for the war, the Nazi mass base
was retained for a while, and even expanded up to a point, despite the
complete identification of the Nazi leadership with German monopoly capital.
War, which brought the entire resources of Europe under the control of
German finance capital, also cemented the social support base for the
open terrorist dictatorship of this finance capital, at least as long
as Germany was winning.
The question naturally arises: was this an exceptional conjuncture which
can now be safely relegated to the pages of history as something horrific,
though sui generis, that had occurred long ago? History no doubt does
not repeat itself with any predictable monotony, but it would be a mistake
not to see certain chilling similarities between the 1930s and now.
True, we do not have today the intense inter-imperialist rivalry of the
early twentieth century, which had produced the First World War, and,
as its sequel, the unbearable burden of war reparations on Germany that
John Maynard Keynes had castigated in his Economic Consequences of the
Peace. But we do have a capitalist crisis that, notwithstanding all protestations
to the contrary, is likely to be as deep and protracted as the one during
the thirties, and associated with it an acute problem of unemployment
that constitutes fertile ground for fascism.
Indeed according to one estimate, if the rate of unemployment were to
be measured today using the same method as was used in the thirties, then
it would turn out to be no lower than during the thirties; and since there
are no prospects of its coming down in the foreseeable future, certain
phenomena that the world had witnessed during the thirties could well
make a distorted reappearance.
It would in fact be no exaggeration to say that world capitalism today
is at an impasse. The neo-liberal regime imposed upon the world by the
ascendancy of globalized finance capital has generated four basic tendencies
which combine to produce this impasse.
The first consists in the fact that free movement of goods and services
and of capital (though not of labour) has made it difficult to sustain
the wage difference between the advanced and backward economies that had
traditionally characterized capitalism. Since the same technology is available
to all economies (and the free movement of capital ensures this), commodities
produced with the cheaper labour that exists in the third world economies
can outcompete those produced in the metropolis. Or, putting it differently,
competition arising from the free movement of goods and services ensures
that workers in the metropolis find their wages being dragged down towards
the levels that prevail in the third world, levels which are no higher,
thanks to the existence of substantial labour reserves, than those needed
to satisfy some historically-determined subsistence requirements. So they
can no longer escape the baneful consequences of third world labour reserves
(themselves the product of colonial and semi-colonuial exploitation that
caused ''deindustrialization'' and a ''drain of surplus''). And even as
wages in the metropolis get dragged down towards those prevailing in the
periphery, labour productivity in the periphery moves up towards the level
prevailing in the metropolis, since such wage differences that still exist
induce a diffusion of activities from the metropolis to the periphery.
This double movement means that the share of wages in the total world
output decreases.
Such a reduction in the share of wages in world output also occurs for
yet another reason: as technological progress in the world economy raises
the level of labour productivity all around, the wages of workers do not
increase pari passu, again owing to these wages being tied to the existence
of substantial labour reserves in the world economy. As a result, taking
the world economy as a whole there is both an increase in income inequalities,
and, as a consequence, a tendency towards underconsumption which makes
the realization of surplus value exceedingly difficult. Credit financed
expenditure and expenditure stimulated by speculative asset price ''bubbles''
provide only temporary antidotes to this tendency towards underconsumption
at the world level, but with the bursting of such ''bubbles'' and the
inevitable termination of such credit financing, the basic underlying
crisis of the world economy reappears with all its intensity.
The second basic tendency that manifests itself under the neo-liberal
regime arises from this. Any deficiency of aggregate demand resulting
in unemployment and recession naturally affects the high-wage and therefore
high-cost producers in the metropolis more severely than the low-wage
countries like India or China. Countries like the United States therefore
experience, as a result of this world tendency towards underconsumption,
not only higher levels of unemployment but also continuous and growing
current account deficits on their balance of payments. In short, acute
unemployment, particularly in the hitherto high-wage economies, and the
so-called problem of ''world imbalances'' (whereby countries like China
have continuous and growing current account surpluses while the United
States has growing deficits and hence gets increasingly indebted) are
both caused by the ubiquity of the neo-liberal regime imposed upon the
world by globalized finance capital. While US multinational corporations
and US financial interests demand neo-liberal regimes everywhere to further
their goals of global domination, the fallout of this demand is reduced
wages and employment for the US workers.
Why, it may be asked, can State intervention in demand management not
overcome this tendency towards world underconsumption and the associated
problem of ''world imbalances''? Here we come to the third tendency of
neo-liberal capitalism, namely that finance capital invariably insists
that all State intervention, all State activism, must be undertaken exclusively
in its own interest. It is not that the State withdraws from intervening,
as is often supposed when the discussion of neo-liberalism is set within
the ''State versus market'' discourse; the nature of State intervention
changes, with the State intervening no longer as an entity perched above
society and apparently impartial between different specific class interests,
but as a defender and promoter of the exclusive interests of finance capital,
on the claim that what is good for finance is good for society. Hence
Keynesian demand management is frowned upon, with most States following
the ''principle of sound finance'' and putting statutory ceilings on fiscal
deficit even as they curtail taxes on the rich. Of course, the State of
the leading economy, the US, whose currency, being almost ''as good as
gold'', enjoys a degree of immunity from the caprices of international
finance capital in this respect, can still undertake demand management
with some impunity, since capital flight away from its currency will still
be generally eschewed. But when the leading-currency country itself is
getting progressively indebted, its ability to undertake demand management
also suffers. In the era of neo-liberalsism therefore there is no effective
leading capitalist State to thwart the tendency towards underconsumption
in the world economy.
Neo-liberalism in other words pushes capitalism towards a protracted crisis
for several reasons: it creates a tendency towards underconsumption in
the world economy by engendering inequalities in income distribution;
it enfeebles capitalist nation-States for undertaking demand management;
and it also undermines the capacity of the leading State for playing a
similar role, but for a different reason, namely by saddling it with continuous
and growing current account deficits.
Economists like Charles Kindleberger have argued that capitalism enters
into a period of deep crisis when there is no effective leader among the
capitalist countries. They attribute the 1930s crisis to the fact that
Britain was no longer able to play its leadership role in the inter-war
period, while the US was as yet unwilling to play this role. In the current
period while the US’s ability to play this role is getting undermined,
there is no alternative leader in sight, which portends a deep and serious
crisis for world capitalism.
It may be thought that the crisis we are talking about is primarily concerned
with the metropolis, which will continue to remain sunk in it for a long
time to come (and if perchance there is a new ''bubble'' that temporarily
lifts it out of this crisis, its inevitable collapse will plunge it back
into crisis), that the third world, especially countries like India, are
immune to it. This, however, is where the fourth tendency of neo-liberal
capitalism becomes relevant. And this relates to the fact that under neo-liberal
capitalism, since the State withdraws from its role of supporting, protecting
and promoting the peasant and petty producers’ economy, which it had taken
upon itself during the dirigiste period as a part of the legacy of the
struggle for decolonization, the decimation of petty production, the unleashing
of a process of primitive accumulation of capital (or what may be more
generally called a process of ''accumulation through encroachment'') proceeds
apace. Multinational retail chains like Walmart come up to displace petty
traders; agribusiness comes in to squeeze the peasantry; land grabbing
financiers come in to displace peasants from their land; and petty producers
of all descriptions everywhere get trapped between rising input prices
and declining output prices. When we add to all this the rise in the cost
of living, because of the privatization of education, health and several
essential services, which affects the entire working population, we can
gauge the virulence of the process of primitive accumulation that is unleashed.
The current period therefore is one where it is not only the advanced
capitalist countries that are beset with crisis and unemployment, but
even apparently ''successful'' ''high growth'' countries like India. The
former are affected by the problem of inadequate demand, the latter by
both the fall-out of the former’s crisis and also by the additional problem
of distress and dispossession of petty producers and the unemployment
enegendered by it. In both segments of the world economy therefore there
arises a tendency towards fascism.
This tendency which has been sporadically evident in Europe through the
rise of extreme right racist political parties has now suddenly manifested
itself menacingly in the United States. Even President Obama’s tepid healthcare
legislation brought forth physcial attacks in Town Hall meetings against
Democratic legislators, not to mention death threats, by hoodlum elements
in the pay of the capitalists; the fact that they were emboldened to do
this reflects the underlying political mood in that country. Indeed sixty-three
percent of what are called ''mainstream Americans'' find the newly formed
extreme right Tea Party to be representing their views! The disllusionment
with the so-called Liberal democratic political elements is complete among
a populace that is battered by unemployment, recession and economic insecurity.
The fact that 13 trillion dollars are pledged to bail out the financial
system, while the government appears profoundly incapable of bringing
down unemployment, strengthens the appeal of fascism. To be sure, this
appeal appears to centre on an opposition to Wall Street and to finance
capital; but finance capital, as in the case of Germany in the 1930s,
is perfectly capable of buying up this opposition itself. While being
the cause of the ''disenchantment against the secular world'', it becomes,
simultaneously and paradoxically, the manipulator of this ''disenchantment'',
directing it against an imagnined or external ''other''; it becomes thereby
the orchestrator of ''unreason'' as well.
Countries like India are not immune to the growth of such fascist tendencies.
Communal fascism already occupies a prominent place in the Indian polity.
But it has several complementary currents, such as the one underlying
Raj Thackeray’s call for ''Mumbai for the Maharashtrians''. In short,
the period of ascendancy of finance capital, albeit in its newly-acquired
garb of international finance capital, has once again brought fascism
back on to the agenda.
Many would argue that nothing comparable to what the world had seen at
the time of the rise of Hitler and Mussolini is visible today, so that
this talk of fascism is just crying wolf. This may be true in the sense
that the intensity of the fascist threat, both as fascism and as threat,
that we are talking about now may not be comparable to what was evident
in the thirties. But any consolation one may derive from this has to be
offset against another basic fact, namely that while in the thirties there
was a massive Left presence, spearheaded by the Soviet Union, against
this threat (which ultimately after all led to its defeat), nothing comparable
exists today. It is all the more important therefore that we remain alert
to the emerging threat of fascism, since the slightest negligence in dealing
with it can exact an even heavier toll today than in the thirties and
forties.
April
28 , 2010.
|