The
ongoing political crisis in Thailand has been capturing
headlines for some time now, and now even appears
to be heading towards some kind of climax. This political
instability reflects more than the resistance of the
existing establishment to the increasingly vociferous
demands of those who have been marginalised from most
of the benefits. It also reinforces the significance
of (and the need for) democratic legitimacy in a developing
country such as Thailand, despite all the known problems
with its electoral process.
But the purely political is not all that underlies
this current crisis. Indeed, it could be argued that
the economic underpinnings of this political crisis
are the more significant forces propelling the actions
of the anti-government protestors. This reflects the
socio-political results of more than a decade in which
the neo-liberal economic model, which still drives
the policy making of the elite, has been fundamentally
exposed among the people.
The conflict between the current Thai government (as
well as those elements of the establishment that directly
and indirectly enabled this particular political grouping
to rule) and the wide spectrum of anti-government
protestors is not simply about certain political processes
or about individuals like Thaksin Shinawatra, the
exiled former Prime Minister. Rather, it is substantially
about economic policy. As Pausk Phongpaichit and Chris
Baker have shown in their excellent book on Thaksin,
he was (and remains) a larger-than-life figure with
only too lifelike faults, which have ranged from blatant
nepotism to megalomaniac attempts at stifling democracy.
So the support for his return is not only (or even
necessarily) because of the craving for a strong leader,
but much more due to the perception that the economic
strategies followed by his government brought at least
some relief to the people.
The continued popularity of Thaksin among the peasants
and otherwise unorganised workers is largely because
of what the Thai elite sniffs away as “populist policies”.
This term is a favourite among chattering classes
across the developing world, used to denigrate any
economic policies with minimally redistributive impact
from the rich and middle classes to the poor. In Thaksin’s
case, these included providing peasants and small
businesses with access to institutional finance, increasing
the share of rural Thailand in public expenditure,
providing fiscal transfers down to the village level
in the form of untied funds to be used according to
the preferences of local communities, and such like.
While these did not contradict or even challenge the
basic neo-liberal framework within which corporate
industry continued to be favoured, they share some
of the spoils of economic growth with those who had
hitherto been excluded. They were certainly popular
policies, and they played a role in giving to Thaksin
and his various political formations a degree of legitimacy
among ordinary people that is still unmatched in Thailand.
While many of Thaksin’s actions in power (and his
own undemocratic tendencies) certainly sowed the seeds
of his decline and fall from grace, the coup and various
other actions of the Thai establishment could also
be seen as the empire striking back. The subsequent
inability of the government to capture the political
imagination of the masses, or even to achieve basic
legitimacy despite trying to continue with some of
Thaksin’s economic policies, may be due to the growing
evidence that even such “populism” is no longer economically
sustainable in Thailand.
To understand this, and also to begin to comprehend
the extent of general dissatisfaction with the economic
regime, it is useful to examine the relationship between
economic growth and employment (which determines the
material conditions of the bulk of the Thai population,
even the peasantry).
Chart 1 shows how real GDP and total employment have
moved over the past twenty five years in Thailand.
Remember that Thailand, in common with many developing
countries, is generally a labour surplus economy engaged
in an uneven and unbalanced process of industrialisation.
Yet it is evident that aggregate GDP growth rates
have run far ahead of aggregate employment growth,
even when the measure of employment includes (as it
does here) all form of self-employment, casual work
and even part-time work.
The period of the Asian crisis occasioned a drop in
GDP as well as in aggregate employment, but the subsequent
sharp recovery in GDP did not translate in more rapid
employment growth, which has tended to stagnate. This
pattern is confirmed by Chart 2, which shows annual
rates of growth of aggregate employment as well as
the unemployment rate. Employment growth has been
volatile within a narrow range, and indicates a trend
decline compared to the 1980s. It was negative at
several points in the 1990s, not only in the crisis
years, and zero in 1999 and again in 2001, reflecting
the effects of the global recession. Subsequently,
despite more respectable aggregate GDP growth, the
peak rates of employment expansion have been less
than 2.5 per cent. Unemployment rates fell somewhat
during the 1980s boom but rose again after the crisis
and since then have displayed volatility around a
higher trend. While these rates may appear low, they
are part of an institutional structure that offers
no social protection to the unemployed, where the
inability to find paid work is therefore reflected
in more disguised unemployment in agriculture and
petty services.
The pattern is a recognisable one. Many developing
countries, including those perceived to be the most
successful in terms of output growth rates, exhibit
this form of jobless growth. This reflects two general
tendencies: a shift in production structure across
and within sectors, whereby income expansion is associated
for demand for goods and services produced in more
capital-intensive conditions without generating demand
for labour-intensive goods and services; and the associated
technological and organisational changes that improve
labour productivity.
This pattern is seen once again in the incidence
of jobless growth in the formal sector, described
in Chart 3. Both in terms of number of establishments
and number of workers, termination of work contracts
was relatively low in the economic boom that preceded
the crisis. However, layoffs zoomed up during the
Asian crisis of 1997-98, and have stayed high in the
entire subsequent period even though the economy supposedly
started booming. In fact, the number of establishments
adversely affected has grown faster during the 2000s
boom, rather than the previous crisis.
Overall, this means a labour market in which workers
are clearly worse off, since both external competitiveness
issues and internal dynamics have dictated that demand
for labour does not keep up with supply. This reduced
bargaining power is indicated by the fact that real
wages – which were drastically affected during the
crisis of 1997-98 – continued to fall even during
the recovery, and then have recovered only slightly.
In 2008, real wages were only 5 per cent higher than
their level of 2000, while labour productivity had
increased by 22 per cent.
Of course these are aggregate figures, and the sectoral
pattern is likely to be more complex. But they indicate
an economy in which the distribution of national income
is clearly shifting away from workers to those who
receive profit, rent and interest. The reduced bargaining
power of workers is inevitably part of the reduced
bargaining power of the peasantry, from whom the ranks
of new workers are generally drawn.
This broader context of worsening income distribution
is essential to understand the current political tensions
in Thailand. The anger of the anti-government protestors
is fundamentally related to this process, and Thaksin
is appreciated by this group only because he showed
that it is still possible at the margins to improve
the lot of the poor using fiscal and monetary policies.
April
20, 2010.
|