IDEAs workshop
on 'Workers, Nation States and the Role of Finance'
26th January, 1.30 pm at PUC (the Catholic University, Porto Alegre),
Building: 15, Room: 228
The workshop was chaired by Erinc Yeldan and the panelists were Jomo K.S.,
Prabhat Patnaik, Ozlem Onaran and Samir Amin. The audience of about a
hundred consisted of academics, activists, people involved in policy-making
and concerned citizens. The workshop sought to clearly articulate, and
therefore to draw the attention of the audience to, the new role of the
'nation-state' in the era of globalization and financial liberalization.
In recent times the state has emerged, not as a producer and investor
and thereby a creator of demand, but, on the contrary, as a controller
of inflation and thereby attractor of foreign capital. The workshop also
discussed the effects of financial liberalization on workers, and explored
possible alternative policies for the future.
In his opening remarks as chairperson, Erinc Yeldan spoke about how ironical
it was that all the developing countries had become nothing but 'emerging
markets' for the north. Their people had lost their individual identities
and their only role was as 'market actors'.
Jomo K.S. began his presentation by introducing IDEAs to the audience.
He discussed its aspirations, beliefs and commitments and invited the
audience to visit the website hosted by IDEAs.
Subsequently, he discussed the role of financial liberalization (FL) that
is now associated with the increasing importance of financial capital
both by itself and in the development of economic theory and practice.
The push for financial liberalization over the last two decades has taken
place at two levels. First, at the domestic level, FL was apparently meant
to destroy so-called 'financial repression'. But in reality it did not.
Second, FL was meant to stop misallocation of scarce resources. But again,
evidence shows that it did not. Not only has there been slower economic
growth and slower reduction in poverty in countries that pursued FL with
zest, there is evidence that FL was associated with rising income inequalities
at both national and international levels.
The intellectual arguments underlying FL have been theoretically weak.
The policies that have been pushed through have their theoretical and
empirical foundations in the work on South Korea by McKinnon and Shaw,
where it was argued that South Korea had a low savings rate because of
the financial repression that allowed banks to keep interest rates down.
FL, it was argued, would free the financial sector from regulation and
raise interest rates. However, the assertions were not borne out even
empirically, since Korea actually had a rising savings rate over the sixties
and the seventies.
Even if the theoretical argument is accepted, McKinnon himself had argued
for a proper sequencing of FL. In reality this was not followed, especially
so in the case of capital account. Reckless FL, for example in South Korea,
has been a major reason for the crises in many developing countries.
The period following FL has proved false many of the claims forwarded
by its proponents. First, it has not resulted in capital flows from the
capital-rich to the capital-poor countries, as claimed. Second, the cost
of finance has risen steeply instead of coming down, as promised by the
proponents of FL. Third, the argument that FL would lead to financial
deepening, which in turn would lead to a stable financial system since
foreign capital would fill in any movements by domestic capital to stabilize
inter-state variations, exchange rate movement, etc., has been proved
to be completely false. Now risk has simply been shifted to a counter
party; so systemic risk is in fact much more concentrated, leading to
a more unstable system. The development of the system and the instruments
of control have therefore made risk more concentrated and more intense.
This is the reason why currency crises have become so common in today's
world. The risk control instruments that have been developed by the IMF
have not addressed the nature of the system itself, and further, any attempt
to find a solution have tended to be subverted by the US government.
Finally, Jomo K.S. made two further interesting points. First with the
increase in the importance of finance, there has been a pressure to follow
deflationary policies - 'inflation targeting' has become the new buzzword,
New Zealand being its pioneer. But this has been the cause of slower economic
growth around the world in the last two decades. Second, for late industrializers,
the availability of long-run development finance is crucial. But with
the advent of financial liberalization, this possibility has almost been
wiped out. Now most regional banks, even those like the Asian Development
Bank, in their bid to emulate the World Bank, have stopped disbursing
long-term development finance. Considering that development in many countries
like Japan, South Korea and Brazil (to name just a few), has heavily depended
on such finance, its unavailability will crucially undermine the process
of development in today's developing economies.
The next speaker, Prabhat Patnaik, highlighted the role of cross-border
flows of capital as finance vis-a-vis the role of the nation-state. This
capital is not meant for creating productive capacity in the form of factories,
etc., but operates just as finance that is highly speculative in nature
and highly global, in the sense that it is free to move anywhere. So now
a new contradiction has emerged between finance that has assumed a global
character and the nation-state that is national. Given the pressures from
the World Bank-IMF, national governments are committed to look after the
interests of global finance and forced to create conditions within their
countries that retain the interests of investors, often to their own detriment.
This implies a withdrawal from the state's domestic role as a producer
and investor, since private investor confidence seems to get adversely
affected by an interventionist state. The nation-state's capacity to intervene
in the economic sphere within its own boundaries therefore gets undermined.
The reasons behind and the implications of this downswing in investor
confidence, occurring as a result of an interventionist state, were clearly
enunciated by Patnaik. First, the fear that the state will interfere is
intensified if a state follows expansionary policies, and this tends to
make capital go out. Second, there is an inherent hostility to state activism
unless it is for the cause of finance. There is also the fear that it
will put up controls and barriers. Third, where the state is inactive
and is withdrawing from the role of producer and investor, it will privatize
its industries and international enterprises will be free to buy these
up very cheap. Fourth, if funds are free to move and interest rates are
the same everywhere, finance has a tendency to move to the north rather
than the south, since the former is the home base of capitalism. So financiers
have to be bribed in the form of a higher real rate of interest, ensuring
that the south is never left with a level playing field. Fifth, if the
real rate of interest is higher the government debt will actually keep
on increasing, and this compounds the problem of public finance for the
nation-state. The national government has now emerged as a protector of
international finance. Capital has always needed a protector domestically,
and since there is no global state, this role has to be performed by nation-states.
The functioning of global financial capital has a recessionary impact
on the entire world economy, but even more so in the third world countries.
Deflation always has an adverse impact on primary producing countries
since the terms of trade always move against agriculture. The whole process
is like re-colonization, characterized by a change in the terms of trade,
no role for the state to provide welfare or productive services, recessionary
policies, etc. It is imperative, therefore, for the developing countries
to put up a resistance, to fight back this process. As history has shown,
pointed out Prabhat Patnaik, growing oppression has always been followed
by growing resistance. Factors like Lula getting elected to power in Brazil
point towards this. But to these must be added deliberate resistance.
Many types of pressures and arm-twisting tactics are being used by the
imperialist powers to subvert such processes, but there is now increasing
protest against these.
The role of the nation-state is crucial in the process of moving back
from globalization and negating its role as a protector of finance capital.
Moving back does not mean a complete reversal but rather an economy with
more controls on trade and capital flows, and one that can ensure tangible
benefits for large sections of the people, which includes fair terms of
trade for the peasantry. The people's support for their national governments
is a must for such a process, and Lula's victory in Brazil could be a
situation to be replicated in all developing countries.
The third speaker, Ozlem Onaran, highlighted the catastrophic impact of
neoliberal policies on labour. She argued that the new era of globalization
that is so consumed with 'inflation targeting' and ensuring the interests
of finance capital has changed the power relations between the working
class and the capitalist class considerably. There are certain features
that this has given rise to. The first is the rise in the power of multinationals
vis-à-vis the power of the nation-state. Second, the increase in
unemployment. Third, the ability of physical and financial capital to
move across borders undermines the bargaining strength of trade unions,
since there will always be the threat that capital will move out. Fourth,
financial capital makes economies more vulnerable by paving the way for
financial crisis in the short run and increasing the long-term rate of
interest in the long run. This also means higher accumulation and lower
growth, which in turn leads to unemployment. The rise of 'short term-ism',
led by shareholder capitalism, is also not good for employment.
As major macroeconomic developments across the world have shown, financial
liberalization, with its discourse of stability and deregulation, actually
brought back a regime of re-regulation, this time in the interests of
the capitalists. In countries of Latin America, Turkey and East Asia,
where they stuck to policies of re-regulation with market fetishism, there
was stagnation in growth and employment, and wages either stagnated or
real wages fell. Despite increased exports, manufacturing employment has
stagnated or fallen. The crisis in Asia did prove that exports have its
constraints. Even strong countries can be victims of overaccumulation
and overindustrialization which make them prone to crises. During the
East Asian crisis, in the two years following 1997, 2 million jobs were
lost. In Turkey, urban unemployment increased from 8 per cent to 13 per
cent during the course of the crisis. During these crises, workers ended
up suffering while capital conveniently flew out.
The future agenda has to come to term with these problems. For this, both
domestic and international policies have to be pressurized away from exploitation
of labour. The policy agenda must include central bank targeting of inflation
and not of unemployment, deregulation of labour markets, regulation of
financial markets, and getting states to formulate effective welfare,
industrial and trade policies that could ensure a redistribution.
Finally, Ozlem Onaran stressed the fact that higher profits could not
lead to higher growth in output and employment. Since the propensity to
consume out of wages is higher than to consume out of profits, the global
economy is more wage-driven than profit-driven. A wage-favouring distribution
is therefore the key to higher demand, and higher growth. The problem
is that policies like this cannot be formulated unless workers are empowered,
but this is difficult with so much unemployment. However, the need of
the people must necessarily be placed before that of profits.
Samir Amin, the final speaker, spoke about the political issues in front
of us with very fundamental economic considerations. He drew the attention
of the audience to the challenges that a new large popular alliance, if
it is sought to be built, would face in the world today.
The fact is that no economy can grow or develop by itself independently
of the social set-up. So even within capitalism, a change in the balance
of forces is crucial. Earlier, the alliance between the workers and peasants
had worked. In today's world, half of the 6 billion people are peasants.
So the question of land and food are crucial at this juncture. Obviously,
producing more food will give a boost to this section of the world population.
But even when more food could be produced, it is the farmers in the US,
and the European Union that have benefited, and most farmers in the world
have not. It is a fact, Amin stressed, that no poor farmer can survive
free competition without subsidies. Any policy that eliminates such subsidies
is therefore obviously planned to benefit developed country peasants and
destroy the others.
The other alternative before the world is not socialism, he argued, but
to have the right of access to land as equal, or at least as little unequal
as possible, for all peasants. This should form the basis for development
and should be a continuous strategy to be pursued even in the future.
Prof. Amin suggested that the earlier commitment to the peasantry has
largely been forgotten, even by left-wing political groups across the
world. Now, even the declaration of human rights does not include any
provision on the right of access to land. This situation needs to be remedied
at once.
Of the other half of the population, two-thirds are the popular classes,
who are not owners of minimum education and minimum resources. These people
are negated in other productive systems. Fifty years ago, they constituted
70 per cent of the world population, and today this proportion is still
high, about 50-60 per cent. This proportion is high even in the north
and is massive in the south.
The change in the attitudes towards these people created the space for
neoliberal economics. The forms of organizational struggle that were effective
earlier have lost their effectiveness now. The need today is for a unified
struggle of labour – both peasant and industrial. Only after that
is there need for articulation in terms of planning, in terms of prices
and incomes, management of balance of payments, tax policies, etc. More
difficult than the economics of such planning is the difficulty of achieving
and converging on that planning and its implementation. But first, the
task before economists is to build a strong worker–peasant alliance.
The audience seemed to be concerned about the economic policy choices
facing President Lula in Brazil today, and this was reflected in the many
questions that were asked. The panelists suggested that Lula needed to
broaden and strengthen his support base among the people (Jomo K.S., Patnaik),
and maybe find some slack from where to give some immediate relief to
his people (Patnaik). All of them agreed that the situation was very complicated
and that Lula had to tread extremely carefully.
Another question asked whether freeing labour mobility could counter the
negative impact of free capital mobility that the speakers had discussed.
The panelists, especially Prabhat Patnaik, answered that it is true that
labour has not been free and this was the major reason for the divide
between the north and the south. But even if it was, labour by its very
nature could not be completely free in a practical sense, since it is
not possible for a labourer in a backward developing country to just go
and settle down in a developed country if he so chose. So that dichotomy
is likely to remain.
Answering questions, including one on Africa, on how to find the resources
and the slack, Ozlem Onaran suggested that the debt of the south needs
to be cancelled, while Prabhat Patnaik suggested a squeezing of foreign
creditors rather than squeezing of people to service debts.
The discussion ended on a note of optimism, but also with recognition
of the new and dangerous threat posed by financial capital to the economic
well-being of developing countries and their peoples.
January 29, 2003. |