Fallacy
1
The interest rate in the Economy
is High because the Fiscal Deficit is high
The interest rate is the return on a particular asset,
namely a debt instrument. It must be determined therefore
as part of a stock equilibrium. The fiscal deficit
is a flow concept. To say that the interest rate is
determined by the size of the fiscal deficit is tantamount
to saying that the price of a stock is determined
by a flow, which is plain illogical.
But, it may be argued, while the fiscal deficit may
not determine the interest rate, it certainly affects
the interest rate, since it adds to the supply of
the stock of debt instruments in the economy by floating
additional government debt. This proposition too is
fallacious, for at least two reasons. But before discussing
these I should clarify a preliminary point: since
debt instruments are also held by banks, whose liabilities
can function as money, to talk of a demand for and
supply of debt instruments independent of the demand
for and supply of money is meaningless; the interest
rate therefore is determined, as every school child
knows, by the demand for and supply of money.
A fiscal deficit then can raise the interest rate
(for a given money supply) through raising the demand
for money via any one of the well-known motives for
holding money (transactions, speculative, precautionary
etc.). It does not constitute ipso facto a corresponding
additional demand for money. Looking at it differently,
the demand for money which affects the interest rate
is the demand for holding money, not the demand for
using money. To say that the demand for and supply
of debt instrument is just the obverse of the demand
for and supply of money, and that therefore the fiscal
deficit which adds to the supply of debt instrument
constitutes ipso facto an additional demand for money
is a fallacy, the first of the two mentioned above.
Just as my borrowing Rs.100 from a friend to buy a
book does not ipso facto constitute a demand for money,
likewise the government's borrowing money to finance
investment (i.e. buy investment goods) does not ipso
facto constitute a demand for money. It may give rise
to a larger demand for money via, for example, increasing
income and hence the transactions demand for money;
but in this respect there is nothing special about
the fiscal deficit. Indeed anything that raises the
money income in the economy has this effect of raising
the demand for money; emphasising the fiscal deficit
has no rationale.
Such emphasis is fallacious for a second reason. In
the above para we took money supply as given. But
whether it is given, or rising, and if rising then
by how much, are all matters of monetary policy. The
interest rate is a monetary phenomenon. It cannot,
at any time, be where it is without monetary policy
keeping it where it is. No amount of fiscal deficit,
or anything else for that matter, can have an iota
of effect on the interest rate if monetary policy
aims otherwise. Therefore if the interest rate is
high, then the question to ask is why a "high
interest rate" monetary policy is being pursued.
The emphasis on the fiscal deficit precludes the asking
of any such question (the answer to which would point
to the fact that, under the new regime of "liberalisation"
where the economy is more open than before to financial
flows, retaining "investors' confidence",
a euphemism for appeasing international finance capital,
becomes necessary).
(Once when I was arguing against a senior economist
from the World Bank that high interest rates had nothing
per se to do with fiscal deficits but were high because
of the pursuit of a monetary policy that kept them
high, his response was: "Oh, but you are talking
about a repressed financial regime!" This amounts
to saying that in a "non-repressed", i.e.
"liberal", financial regime, interest rates
are high because of fiscal deficits. This argument
has four notable features. First, it contains a tautology,
since a "repressed" financial regime is
by definition one where the interest rates are kept
low. His argument in other words amounts to saying:
"interest rates are high because in a high -interest
rate regime, fiscal deficit keeps them high"!
Secondly, the argument contains a non-sequitur. Once
the tautology is recognised, dragging in the fiscal
deficit introduces a complete non-sequitur. Thirdly,
it is ideological. In presenting a non-sequitur he
could have put in any term other than the fiscal deficit
without altering by one iota the status of the argument
in terms of its veracity. For instance, he could as
well have said: "interest rates are high because
in a high interest rate regime a high level of consumption
keeps them so"! The fact that he chose fiscal
deficit is indicative of the Bank's ideology. And
fourthly, this tautology with an ideologically-motivated
non-sequitur does not have one iota of explanatory
power.)
Fallacy 2
A Large Fiscal Deficit is Necessarily
Harmful
There are three possible
adverse consequences of a fiscal deficit (I am excluding
such consequences as "lowering investors' confidence",
since they arise only in a particular regime, of "liberalisation",
which itself has no sanctity). First, it may generate
excess demand pressures in the economy, giving rise
to inflation and/or a current account deficit on the
balance of payments. Secondly, a fiscal deficit generates
wealth inequalities in society. An excess of expenditure
over income of the government must be matched by an
excess of income over expenditure of the non-government
sectors (i.e. of the private sector and the "rest
of the World"). We have already mentioned the
problem of enlarged foreign debt (which arises from
a larger current account deficit on the BOP); so let
us leave the "rest of the world" out. Financing
government expenditure through larger domestic borrowing
implies (relative to either not having this expenditure
at all or financing it through taxes) larger private
wealth. Since the propensity to save is larger among
the rich, this necessarily means larger wealth in
their hands; wealth inequalities therefore increase.
What is particularly bizarre is when fiscal deficit
causes inflation: here inflation squeezes out forced
savings from the poor and working people, but these
savings add to the wealth of the rich (Keynes had
rejected such "deficit financing" in How
to Pay for the War). Thirdly, deficit-financed expenditure
(relative again to either tax-financed expenditure
or to no such expenditure) sets up a debt-service
obligation upon the government, which may aggravate
fiscal strain in the future.
In a demand-constrained system the first of these
adverse consequences would be inoperative (such a
system may still experience a current account deficit
following a fiscal deficit, since imports increase
with output, but this is not specifically related
to the fiscal deficit; any other way of enlarging
output by a similar magnitude would have generated
an equal current deficit). The other two adverse consequences
of course would still remain. But this means that
in a demand-constrained system, while it may be better
to finance enlarged government expenditure through
taxes (provided they do not nullify expansion) rather
than through a deficit, it may still be preferable
to have a deficit rather than not expand expenditure
at all. A large fiscal deficit need not be shunned
in a demand-constrained system.
But the matter appears in an altogether different
light when we use the term fiscal deficit in the conventional
sense in which it is used in India. Here fiscal deficit
refers not to the deficit of the government sector
as a whole but only to the excess of expenditure over
income in the government budget. Since a large part
of government activity is not covered in the budget,
it is perfectly possible that the fiscal deficit as
revealed in the budget is matched by a corresponding
surplus not in private hands (we leave out the external
sector for the moment), but in the hands of the non-budget
sector of the government itself. If this happens,
then the concern over private wealth inequalities
and possible future fiscal strain (owing to debt-service
payments) need not be serious. If the economy in addition
happens to be demand-constrained, then a fiscal deficit
need have no adverse consequences at all. Indeed in
such a situation curtailing government expenditure
in the name of keeping down the fiscal deficit would
be a foolish policy to pursue, because it would perpetuate
the demand constraint which could have been removed
"costlessly" (i.e. with no adverse consequences).
The foolishness would be truly astounding if, even
in the presence of idle capacity located within the
government sector itself, not only is fiscal deficit,
which would have generated demand for using up this
capacity, kept down, but "shortage of rupee resources"
is simultaneously invoked as an argument to invite
foreign investment to set up plants with the import
of the very equipment whose production capacity is
lying idle within the government sector.
In India, regrettably, fallacy 2 has become the cornerstone
of official macroeconomic thinking; what is more,
government policy even pursues the "astoundingly
foolish" course just mentioned. Let me give two
examples to illustrate my point.
At present there are over 32 million tonnes of foodgrain
stocks of which at least 13 million tonnes are surplus
stocks. These surplus stocks should be used to alleviate
poverty and hunger through an employment-generation
programme, which, if properly conceived and executed,
can have the additional advantage of giving rise to
rural capital formation. Even if this programme is
financed entirely through deficit financing, this
would have no adverse consequences: the money spent
would accrue to the FCI (ignoring for simplicity the
non-food component of the employment-programme), which
in turn would use it to repay bank-credit locked up
in stock-holding. The government's net indebtedness
would not have gone up; its total interest payment
obligation would not have gone up (would have even
come down if government borrowing costs less than
FCI borrowing); and yet rural poverty would have come
down through the elimination (even if temporary) of
the irrational spectre of unused rotting foodstocks
in the midst of mass hunger. True, the fiscal deficit
shown in the budget would have gone up, but attributing
economic significance to this fact per se is precisely
the fallacy we are talking about. The current budget
however undertakes no such programme. On the contrary
it does the very opposite: it attempts to bring down
this wrongly-conceived notion of deficit by raising
food prices for all and by virtually winding up the
public distribution system for the so-called "above
poverty line" population which actually includes
vast numbers of the poor.
My second example relates to the power sector. There
is an almost unanimous view in government and media
circles that India desperately needs foreign capital
to develop its power sector. But this need cannot
be for technology (which we have) or for foreign exchange
(which would not be required in the first place if
domestically produced equipment is used). The only
possible argument in support of this view can be that
MNCs bring finance, that if they were not entrusted
with the task then the government would have to finance
these power projects from its budgetary resources,
which typically would mean a larger fiscal deficit.
In short, power projects are being entrusted to MNCs
in order to avoid a larger fiscal deficit. But, as
long as unutilised capacity owing to deficient demand
exists in the power equipment and its feeder units
belonging to the public sector itself, to talk of
the government's experiencing a shortage of finance
for power investment is meaningless. If the government
borrowed Rs.100 and spent it on a power project then
the bulk of it would come back as operating surplus
to BHEL and other public sector enterprises, so that
the net indebtedness of the government would not increase
despite the apparent increase in the fiscal deficit.
But by invoking a financial constraint where none
exists, the government not only succumbs to MNCs'
demand for their "pound of flesh" (including
guaranteed rates of return on inflated capital costs),
but also perpetuates the demand constraint faced by
the public sector units. What is more, this perpetuation
would be used as an argument for declaring these units
to be "sick" and for privatising them 'for
a song". The most charitable interpretation one
can place on government action is the one I have placed,
namely that it betrays "astounding foolishness".
Fallacy 3
Disinvesting public sector
equity is a valid way of closing the fiscal deficit
I argued above that there could be only three possible
adverse consequences of a fiscal deficit. Now, disinvestment
of public sector equity, as compared to a fiscal deficit,
makes no difference to wealth inequalities; the private
sector only swaps direct or indirect claims upon the
government for public sector equity. There is in other
words a change in the form of wealth-holding, not
in the magnitude or distribution of it as would happen
with by a fiscal deficit. Likewise, while a fiscal
deficit sets up interest payment obligations upon
the government, disinvestment of public sector equity
entails foregoing future incomes (on this more later),
so that there is nothing to choose between the two
in terms of the future fiscal strain. The claim that
disinvestment of public sector equity is a valid way
of closing the fiscal deficit, i.e. would somehow
ameliorate the harmful consequences of a fiscal deficit,
can be sustained therefore only if it entails less
excess demand pressures than a corresponding fiscal
deficit would.
This would indeed be the case if those who purchased
public sector equity did so by reducing their consumption
or investment. Now, to my knowledge, no protagonist
of the sale of public sector equity has ever argued
that such sale "crowds out" private investment
(for then the case for such sale would be considerably
weakened). And nobody surely believes that people
stint on consumption to purchase public sector equity.
The purchase of public sector equity in other words
has scarcely any flow-expenditure-diminishing effect
on the private sector.
It may be thought that while such purchase may not
directly reduce flow private expenditure, if it is
financed by borrowing then less credit may be available
for deployment in other uses, resulting in an indirect
curtailment of private flow expenditure. But this
argument is both empirically questionable and logically
untenable. It presupposes a supply constraint on credit,
which is empirically questionable for large chunks
of the nineties, including now. Besides, if indeed
credit were supply-constrained, then the financing
of the fiscal deficit itself would have curtailed
private flow expenditure, so that the fiscal deficit
would not have generated excess demand in the first
place, and the need for covering it would not have
arisen at all.
Now, if disinvesting public sector equity does not
reduce flow private expenditure, then the claim that
it is a valid way of covering the fiscal deficit falls
to the ground. Instead of the government borrowing
Rs.100, say, from the banks to finance its expenditure
(which is what a fiscal deficit entails), someone
else borrows Rs.100 from the banks, hands it to the
government in lieu of public sector equity, and the
government then spends it. The macroeconomic consequences,
in terms of aggregate demand, are exactly the same
in the two cases. If with a fiscal deficit there was
going to be excess demand-generated inflation, then
exactly the same denouement would follow from public
sector disinvestment. If the poor were going to be
hit by a fiscal deficit-caused inflation in the first
scenario, they would be equally hit in the second.
But the second scenario entails a gratuitous handing
over of public sector equity to private hands on the
basis of false claims (of avoiding the ill-effects
of a fiscal deficit).
Fallacy 4
Selling Public Enterprises
to Retire Government Debt reduces Future Fiscal Strain
This argument has been put forward quite explicitly
by the Finance Minister himself in his recent budget
speech. The price at which a public enterprise (or
its equity) sells in the market is determined by the
discounted value of its expected stream of returns.
Suppose, for example, that a public enterprise is
expected to fetch for an an infinite period in the
future stream of returns of Rs.10 every year. If the
interest rate is 10 percent, then its market value
would be Rs.100 (we are ignoring risks for simplicity);
and if these Rs.100 are used for retiring public debt,
then the interest payments saved every year are exactly
Rs.10. The government in other words has lost Rs.10
per annum of returns from the enterprise and has saved
Rs.10 per annum of interest payments. It is neither
better nor worse off; there is no easing of its fiscal
strain in the future.
Selling public enterprises to retire debt would indeed
be worthwhile if and only if the enterprise sells
for a price higher than the market value figure obtained
when the stream of returns expected from it (when
it is under government ownership) is discounted at
the rate of interest payable on public debt. This
translates roughly into the proposition that such
a course of action is worthwhile for the government,
and would ease future fiscal strain, if the enterprise
sells for a price higher than its current market value
(at the interest rate on public debt). On the other
hand if it sells for a lower price than its market
value (at the public debt rate of interest), then
the future fiscal situation is worsened.
Now, there is absolutely no reason why the enterprise
should sell at a higher price than this market value;
and none of those who advocate such sale has ever
made out a case that this indeed would happen. On
the contrary, as everybody knows and as testified
to by a host of authorities from the Comptroller and
Auditor General of India to an impeccable "liberaliser"
like Mr.Chidambaram (in the GAIL disinvestment case),
the sale of public sector equity is usually way below
its market value, which only worsens the fiscal situation
in the future. Not only then is there no case for
selling public enterprises to retire public debt,
but it is actually a "rip off" which only
worsens the fiscal situation in the future.
One can go on with the list of fallacies. In fact
a whole phoney macroeconomics is being propagated
these days from the Bretton Woods institutions, which
unfortunately, even in this country with its remarkable
tradition of economics, has been swallowed not only
by our Finance Ministry but even by large segments
of the economics profession. How else can one explain
the fact that despite evidence of growing rural poverty,
of a "rolling back" of rural employment
diversification, of an absolute drop in per capita
real consumption expenditure in rural India (which
my colleague Sheila Bhalla has called an "economic
development disaster"), and of persisting industrial
stagnation, the most significant problem of the economy
highlighted in the media is the fiscal deficit! And
that too in the midst of huge unutilised industrial
capacity and unsold foodgrain stocks!
May be I am being unfair. My claim about the above
propositions constituting fallacies is based on macroeconomics
no more complex than IS-LM. I would like any of those
who believe in the correctness of the above propositions
to set out simply but rigourously, in the manner of
IS-LM, what their macroeconomics is. Only one thing
I cannot accept: a "liberal regime", "the
need to retain investors' confidence" etc. cannot
be premises of the argument, they can only be conclusions.
"Liberalisation" has to be shown to be good
for the people; people cannot be assumed to exist
for making "liberalisation" work. For the
rest, I go along with Joan Robinson: "Let a hundred
flowers bloom. Let a thousand schools of thought contend.
But let them all state their assumptions."
January 15, 2002.
|