Pundits
agree this is merely the latest in a string of bail-outs,
led by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), that
squandered billions of dollars and failed to save
the economies they were meant to help.
Some claim the IMF was too lenient while others say
it was too tough. And some see the problem as self-inflicted
through profligate and corrupt spending by Argentina
.Such attempts at blame-shifting are misguided: The
default can be seen as the result of economic mistakes
made over a decade. Understanding what went wrong
provides important lessons.
The problems began with the hyper-inflation of the
1980s. To slash inflation, expectations needed changing;
'anchoring' the currency to the dollar was meant to
do this. If inflation continued, the country's real
exchange rate would appreciate, demand for its exports
fall and unemployment increase, dampening wage and
price pressures. Market participants, knowing this,
would realise inflation would not be sustained. While
the commitment to the exchange-rate system remained
credible, so did the commitment to halt inflation.
If inflationary expectations were changed, then disinflation
could occur without costly unemployment. This prescription
worked for a time in a few countries, but was risky,
as Argentina was to show.
The IMF encouraged this exchange-rate system. Now
it is less enthusiastic, though Argentina is the one
paying the price. The peg lowered inflation but did
not promote sustained growth. Argentina should have
been encouraged to fix a more flexible exchange rate,
or at least a rate more reflective of its trading
patterns.
There were other mistakes in Argentina's 'reform'
programme. It was praised for allowing large foreign
ownership of banks. This led to a seemingly more stable
banking system, but one which failed to lend to small-
and medium-sized firms.
After the burst of growth which came with hyper-inflation's
end, growth slowed, partly because firms could not
get adequate finance. The government recognised the
problem, but was hit by numerous shocks beyond its
control before it could act. East Asia's crisis of
1997 provided the first shock. Partly because of IMF
mismanagement, this became a global financial crisis,
raising interest rates for all emerging markets, including
Argentina.
Argentina's exchange-rate system survived, but at
a heavy price - double-digit unemployment. Soon, high
interest rates strained the country's budget. Yet
its debt to gross domestic product (GDP) ratio remained
moderate, at around 45 per cent, lower than Japan's.
But with 20 per cent interest rates, 9 per cent of
the country's GDP would be spent annually on financing
its debt.
The government pursued fiscal austerity, but not enough
to make up for the vagaries of the market. The global
financial crisis that followed East Asia's crisis
set off a series of big exchange-rate adjustments.
The US dollar, to which Argentina's peso was tied,
increased sharply in value. Meanwhile, Argentina's
neighbor and Mercosur trading partner, Brazil, saw
its currency depreciate.
Wages and prices fell, but not enough to allow Argentina
to compete effectively, especially as many agricultural
goods, which constitute Argentina's natural advantages,
face high hurdles in entering rich countries' markets.
The world had hardly recovered from the 1997-1998
financial crisis when the 2000 2001 global slowdown
started, worsening Argentina's situation. Here the
IMF made its fatal mistake: It encouraged a concretionary
fiscal policy, the same mistake it had made in East
Asia.
Fiscal austerity was supposed to restore confidence.
But the numbers in the IMF programme were fiction;
any economist would have predicted that concretionary
policies would incite slow-down, and that budget targets
would not be met.
Needless to say, the IMF programme did not fulfill
its commitments. Confidence is seldom restored as
an economy goes into a deep recession and double-digit
unemployment. Perhaps a military dictator could have
suppressed the social and political unrest that arises
in such conditions.But in Argentina's democracy, this
was impossible. I was more surprised unrest took so
long to manifest itself, than that street turmoil
unseated Argentina's president.
Seven lessons must now be drawn: In a world of volatile
exchange rates, pegging a currency to one like the
US dollar is highly risky. Globalisation exposes a
country to enormous shocks. Adjustments in exchange
rates are part of the coping mechanism. You ignore
social and political contexts at your peril. Any government
following policies which leave large parts of the
population unemployed or underemployed is failing
in its primary mission.A single-minded focus on inflation
without a concern for unemployment or growth - is
risky.
Growth requires financial institutions
that lend to domestic firms. Selling banks to foreign
owners, without appropriate safeguards, may impede
growth and stability. One seldom restores economic
strength - or confidence - with policies that force
an economy into a deep recession.
Better ways are needed to deal with situations like
Argentina's. I argued for this during East Asia's
crisis; the IMF preferred its big bail-out strategy.
Now it belatedly recognises that it should explore
alternatives. The IMF will work hard to shift blame
- there will be allegations of corruption, and claims
Argentina did not pursue needed measures. Of course,
it needed to undertake other reforms - but following
the IMF's advice made matters worse.
Argentina's crisis should remind us of the pressing
need to reform the global financial system - and thorough
reform of the IMF is where we must begin.
The writer, a professor
of economics at Columbia University, won the Nobel
Prize for Economics last year. He was formerly chairman
of the Council of Economic Advisers to then US President
Bill Clinton, and chief economist and senior vice-president
of the World Bank.
MORE ON ARGENTINA
CRISIS
January 10, 2002.
[Source: The Straits Times January 10, 2002]
This material is distributed without profit to those
who have expressed a prior interest in receiving this
information for research and educational purposes.
|