The dollar is on the decline, with its
value having fallen by around 30 per cent relative to other major currencies
since 2002 and by close to 20 per cent in trade-weighted terms. Yet, the
US government feigns being unconcerned with the problem. In the G-20 meeting
held in the second half of November, the US Treasury Secretary reportedly
refused to talk about the dollar's decline, though he reiterated the Bush
administration's public commitment to halve the US government's budget
deficit during its second term and bring it below two per cent of GDP.
The relevance of the budget deficit for the problem at hand is obvious,
given the connection between the dollar's decline and the twin deficits
in the USthe balance of payments deficit amounting to 5.5 per cent of
GDP and the fiscal deficit to 4.2 per cent of GDP. With savings rates
close to zero on average, private spending is high in the US. But a large
part of the demand this generates spills over into the international market
given the lack of competitiveness of US producers. However, this has not
resulted in a domestic recession because the government has in recent
years been pump-priming the economy with deficit spending (though a part
of that too leaks out abroad). In the event, the US has required the two
deficits to sustain its reasonable rate of growth by developed country
standards.
These deficits have not proved a problem because of capital inflows, including
in the form of investment of surpluses accumulated by foreign governments
and central banks in dollar denominated financial assets. According to
one source, in 2002, 2003 and the first half of 2004, foreign governments
financed $564bn (43 per cent) of a cumulative current account deficit
of $1,318bn (£695bn). The problem recently has been that both private
wealthholders and foreign governments have begun to fear that the unsustainable
value of the dollar spells a decline in the currency that could sharply
erode the value of their assets. The resulting rearrangement of their
portfolio away from dollar assets in favour of other currencies is what
explains the dollar's decline.
At one level this decline appears to be a boon to the US. It cheapens
the foreign exchange value of its exports and renders imports more expensive
in dollar terms, improving US competitiveness. If this helps reduce the
trade deficit, the size of the fiscal deficit needed to keep growth going
would be lower. A process of self-correction seems to be providing a solution
to the twin deficit problem.
The difficulty, however, is that the dollar's decline would also result
in lower inflows into and larger outflows into US capital markets, resulting
in a fall in financial asset prices that would reduce the wealth position
of US households and institutions. This would reduce consumer spending
and curtail demand. That problem could be aggravated by a possible liquidity
crunch in the system, as banks and financial institutions experiencing
a depreciation of their asset values turn cautious. Further, lower financial
asset prices imply higher interest rates that could affect investment
adversely as well. Thus a correction of the twin deficit problem through
a depreciation of the dollar could also imply a recession in the US.
All this makes the dollar's decline a problem for the rest of the world
as well, especially countries in Europe and in Asia, like China, that
are heavily dependent on the US market. Dollar depreciation increases
the dollar value of their exports to the US and undermines their competitiveness
and recessionary trends in the US would squeeze an important market for
their exports.
It is this global effect of the dollar's decline that the US exploits
to make the decline everybody's problem and not just its own. In its view,
the twin deficit problem can be best resolved through increased net exports
(exports net of imports) from the US. This would reduce the trade deficit,
contribute to demand for US goods and help reduce the fiscal deficit without
affecting growth adversely. So, Europe, Japan and China must help raise
net exports from the US.
The G-20 meeting in November saw the Europe and Japan partly going along
with the US on this count. ''The Group of 20 leading rich and emerging
market nations have agreed on a co-ordinated effort to reduce global trade
imbalances by cutting the US fiscal deficit, reforms to boost growth in
Europe and Japan and increasing exchange rate flexibility in Asia,'' reported
the Financial Times on November 22. That is, the reduction of the US fiscal
deficit was made contingent on reflation in Europe and Japan which, hopefully,
would expand the market for US goods, and reduced currency intervention
by Asian governments aimed at pegging their currencies to the dollar.
The latter, by resulting in an appreciation of Asian currencies vis-à-vis
the dollar is expected to increase the competitiveness of US exports to
these countries and therefore in an increase in the volume of US exports.
The country which would be most effected by the second of these recommendations
is China, which has pegged the value of its currency the renminbi (yuan)
at 8.27 to a dollar since 1997. China has been under pressure for quite
some time to revalue its currency and redress the ''imbalance'' that its
trade surplus ($124 billion last year) with the US (Chart 1) and its large
foreign exchange reserves ($514.5 billion) ostensibly reflect. That pressure
has now increased, since Europe and Japan would like to see China bearing
a larger share of the burden of global adjustment, by curtailing its exports
and increasing its imports with a flexible and appreciating currency.
China's fears on this count are not just related to its trading position.
It is more worried about the effects of introducing a more flexible currency
and allowing the yuan to appreciate on its currency and financial markets.
A stronger yuan is bound to spur large capital inflows, while capital
account restrictions do not permit money to flow out easily. This would
increase reserves further and drive the yuan even higher. And once that
happens, speculation on the value of the yuan can increase capital inflows
even more. Such a spiral can be destabilising and weaken autonomy in monetary
policy.
Not surprisingly, China is not happy. In an interview with the Financial
Times, Li Ruogu, the deputy governor of the People's Bank of China, warned
the US not to blame other countries for its economic difficulties. ''China's
custom is that we never blame others for our own problem,'' he reportedly
said. ''For the past 26 years, we never put pressure or problems on to
the world. The US has the reverse attitude, whenever they have a problem,
they blame others.''
There were three unexceptional arguments that Li used to justify his criticism.
First, "The savings rate in China is more than 40 per cent. In the
US it is less than 2 per cent. So the problem is that they spend too much
and save too little." Second, there was a lack of correspondence
between US wages and productivity resulting from the tendency of the government
to protect low productivity jobs. US workers enjoyed relatively high wages
but remained excessively engaged in low value-added industries such as
textiles and agriculture. Finally, US policies discriminate against exports
of goods that China needs. Restrictions on exports of military and high-technology
products to China partly explains Beijing's huge trade surplus with America,
he argues.
In fact, the evidence on China's trade does not support the view that
it adopts a mercantilist policy that pushes exports and restricts imports.
In 2003, while exports of goods and services amounted to 33 per cent of
GDP, imports of goods and services stood at 32 per cent of GDP (Chart
2). At present, China records an overall trade deficit, which is expected
to touch $40 billion in 2004. In the first four months of 2004, China's
exports amounted to $162.7 billion, up 33.5 per cent from a year ago.
Imports on the other hand rose 42.4 per cent to $173.5 billion, resulting
in an overall trade deficit of $10.8 billion. A negative trade balance
is sure proof that mercantilism does not drive trade and economic policy.
The reason why China is susceptible to international pressure despite
this trade record is the country-wise distribution of its exports and
imports. In 2003, merchandise imports from China into the US amounted
to $163.2 billion, or 12.5 per cent of its total merchandise imports.
This figure had risen from 6.3 per cent in 1995. Imports into the European
Union and Japan amounted to $107.8 billion (3.7 per cent) and $75.4 billion
(19.7 per cent). Though relative to the total Japan was a major importer,
the US clearly dominated in absolute magnitude. What is more, merchandise
exports to China in 2003 stood at $28.4 billion, $44.9 billion and $72.5
billion respectively in the case of the US, European Union and Japan.
The US sucks in commodities from China, but sends little back in return.
Finally, in recent years, China has provided space for foreign firms
in its domestic market. As Nicholas Lardy, then of the Brookings Institution,
wrote in 2002: At the turn of the twenty-first century in China, ''foreign
manufacturers led by Motorola, Nokia and Ericsson had captured 95 per
cent of the market for cellular phones. Coca-Cola was the dominant supplier
of carbonated beverages with a market share fifteen times its closest
domestic competitor. Its operations in China have been profitable for
more than a decade, and Coca-Cola expects China to emerge as its largest
Asian market in 2002 or 2003. McDonald's and Kentucky Fried Chicken, with
almost 900 outlets between them, dominated China's rapidly growing food
market. Kodak had captured half the market for film and photographic paper.
Volkswagen, through two separate joint ventures, controlled more than
half the domestic automobile industry. Carrefour, the French company,
had become China's second largest retailer only five years after entering
the market. And, as unlikely as it might have once seemed, Proctor and
Gamble had more than half of what is undoubtedly the world's biggest shampoo
market.''
Thus, the problem is not one of Chinese mercantilism, but one of lack
of competitiveness of the US. Not surprisingly, the US has performed poorly
despite the fact that the yuan is pegged to the dollar. With the dollar
depreciating vis-à-vis the euro and the yen, it is the EU and Japan
that should lose out in trade with China, not the US.
Despite all this evidence in its favour, China is feeling the heat, as
shown by Li Ruogu's response. This is the result of China's reform-driven
dependence on exports in general and exports to the US in particular.
With exports amounting to 33 per cent of GDP and the US accounting for
37 per cent of China's total merchandise exports of $438.4 billion, the
US market is too important for China for US views to be ignored. Not surprisingly,
expectations are that China would soon loosen strings on the yuan, which
has since 1995 been allowed to fluctuate only within a ultra-narrow 0.3
per cent band around 8.28 yuan to the dollar. That band is now expected
to widen. But this is likely to be too slow to satisfy the US because
of what investment banker Henry Liu sees as China's ''residual commitment
to socialist principles'', which makes it hope that it can ''reap the
euphoria of market fundamentalism without succumbing to its narcotic addiction.''
The US and the rest of the world will have to find some other answer to
the problem of the weakening dollar generated by the twin deficits in
the US.
December 25, 2004.
|