On April 4, the US Department of Commerce succumbed
to protectionist pressures and chose to launch investigations
to check whether textile imports from China were disrupting
US markets. US Commerce Secretary, Carlos Gutierrez,
is reported to have said that the decision was "the
first step in a process to determine whether the US
market for these products is being disrupted and whether
China is playing a role in that disruption".
The immediate excuse was evidence of a sharp rise
in the quantum of imports of certain varieties of
Chinese textiles into the US market, quota restrictions
on which under the Multi-Fibre Agreement (MFA) were
lifted as of January 1, 2005. As Table 1 indicates,
import increases during the first quarter of the year
in select categories that are controversial have varied
from an excess of 250 per cent to as much as 1600
per cent. However, there is need for caution when
quoting these figures, because they are growth rates
computed on a base kept low by the MFA's quota regime.
Table 1: Increase in Imports
of Specific Categories of Textiles: Jan-March 2005
Category |
Volume
Growth (Percentage) |
Cotton Hosiery |
1084 |
Cotton Knit Shirts,
MB |
1003 |
W/G Knit Blouse |
1499 |
Cotton Skirts |
1102 |
Cot.M/B Trousers |
1492 |
W/G Slacks, etc. |
1612 |
Cotton Underwear |
408 |
M-MF Underwear |
260 |
Source: US Department
of Commerce, Preliminary Data |
|
But touting such figures,
US industry associations have been accusing the Chinese
of dumping to an extent that disrupts the US market
and damages the domestic industry. In the event, they
are demanding that the government should invoke a
clause included in China's WTO accession conditions
that permits the US government to restrict import
growth to 7.5 per cent a year till 2008. The Bush
government that has recently begun its second term
has been quick to oblige, even though domestic political
pressures are not as overwhelming.
There are, however, a number of reasons to hold that
the US response is either alarmist or orchestrated
to justify a protectionist response. We must recognise
that quotas under the MFA, which limited the quantum
of exports into individual segments of the global
textile market from the most competitive textile exporters,
had two kinds of effects. First, it reduced the competition
faced by US (domestic) suppliers of textiles from
imports from the most cost-competitive centres of
global textile production, allowing the former to
sustain higher levels of output. Second, it reduced
competition between exporters from more and less competitive
locations targeting the same market, by restricting
the volume of exports from more competitive producers.
As a result of these
two different forces at play, the lifting of quotas
was expected to have two different effects. One was
an increase in the total quantum of imports of restricted
items into individual markets because of increased
imports from all locations that are cost-competitive
relative to domestic suppliers. The second was a re-division
of an individual market among exporters, with more
cost-competitive suppliers displacing less cost-competitive
ones in individual segments.
Taiwan refers to Taiwan
province of China |
As Chart 1 makes clear,
both these tendencies are visible in the US market.
Considering all items of textile and apparel imports,
the US trade balance report which provides the most
comprehensive data, indicates that total imports into
the US market rose by close to 20 per cent in the
first two months of 2005 (relative to the corresponding
period of the previous year) as compared with 8.3
per cent during 2004. Thus the removal of quotas did
result in a substantial increase in imports into the
US market that would have resulted in some displacement
of domestic production.
However, the increase
in imports from China, which amounted to 60.5 per
cent during January-February 2005 as compared with
25.3 per cent in 2004, was not wholly directed at
the displacement of US production. Rather, increased
imports from China were accompanied by a decline or
slowing down of imports from other sources such as
Mexico, South Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan province of
China and Japan. That is, after the removal of quotas,
Chinese imports were outcompeting imports into the
US from other sources that were earlier "protected"
by the MFA regime.
Taiwan refers to Taiwan
province of China |
This
is not to say, however, that China is wiping the floor
clean. There are other countries such as the EU-15,
the ASEAN countries and countries belonging to the
Caribbean Basin Initiative (CBI) that have been able
to increase the rate of expansion of their exports.
What is disconcerting however is that the Least Developed
Countries (LDCs), which do not receive the same special
benefits as the CBI group in US markets, have seen
a significant decline in the rate of growth of their
exports to the US market. But this may partly be due
to the disruption caused by the tsunami in at least
some of these countries, such as Mauritius.
Some of these features are sharper if we consider
an area like apparel, which is where the bulk of the
increase in imports into the US from China has taken
place. As Chart 2 indicates, while China's apparel
exports to the US grew by close to 75 per cent during
the first two months of 2005, as compared with 23
per cent during 2004, this was accompanied by a substantial
degree of displacement of imports from Canada, Mexico,
South Korea, Hong Kong and Taiwan province of China.
Further, besides increases in imports from country-groupings
such as the EU-15, ASEAN and the CBI, LDCs have registered
a much smaller decline in the rate of growth of imports
than is suggested by aggregate figures.
In sum, not all of
China's dramatic export increase during the first
quarter of 2005 was on account of the displacement
of US production. It was partly because of displacement
of export increases from other countries. And there
were countries other than China which contributed
to the growth in overall textile imports into the
US. Above all, as Table 2 makes clear, the effect
of the increase in Chinese exports on exports to the
US from individual developing countries has not been
as adverse as had been expected.
Table 2: US Textile Imports
by Country Major Shipper's Report ($ Mill.)
|
|
|
|
|
Growth
Rate |
|
2003 |
2004 |
Jan-Feb 2004 |
Jan-Feb 2005 |
Jan-Feb
2004 |
Jan-Feb
2005 |
World |
77434 |
83312 |
12284.1 |
14010 |
7.6 |
14.0 |
China |
11608.8 |
14559.9 |
2002.9 |
3362.4 |
25.4 |
67.9 |
Asean |
11678.2 |
12143.6 |
1867.7 |
2014 |
4.0 |
7.8 |
CAFTA |
9244.6 |
9578.6 |
1266.9 |
1408.4 |
3.6 |
11.2 |
EU-15 |
4336.5 |
4530 |
687.5 |
730.9 |
4.5 |
6.3 |
Sub-Sahara |
1534.9 |
1781.8 |
253.2 |
282.5 |
16.1 |
11.6 |
Bangladesh |
1939.4 |
2065.7 |
324.6 |
359.4 |
6.5 |
10.7 |
Cambodia |
1251.2 |
1441.7 |
234.3 |
259.1 |
15.2 |
10.6 |
Fiji |
79.6 |
85.8 |
13.9 |
7.7 |
7.8 |
-44.6 |
India |
3211.5 |
3633.4 |
588.1 |
737 |
13.1 |
25.3 |
Indonesia |
2375.7 |
2620.2 |
445.4 |
477.6 |
10.3 |
7.2 |
Japan |
522.4 |
641.7 |
78.3 |
79.8 |
22.8 |
1.9 |
South Korea |
2567 |
2579.7 |
393.9 |
344.3 |
0.5 |
-12.6 |
Laos |
3.9 |
2.1 |
0.3 |
0.1 |
-46.2 |
-66.7 |
Malaysia |
737.5 |
764.3 |
117.3 |
109.8 |
3.6 |
-6.4 |
Maldives |
93.7 |
81 |
12.5 |
4.7 |
-13.6 |
-62.4 |
Mauritius |
269.1 |
226.6 |
43.1 |
37.5 |
-15.8 |
-13.0 |
Mexico |
7940.8 |
7793.3 |
1144.9 |
1097.2 |
-1.9 |
-4.2 |
Mongolia |
181.1 |
229.1 |
25.8 |
21.7 |
26.5 |
-15.9 |
Nepal |
155.3 |
130.6 |
25.9 |
16 |
-15.9 |
-38.2 |
Pakistan |
2215.2 |
2546 |
371.4 |
396.9 |
14.9 |
6.9 |
Philippines |
2040.3 |
1938.1 |
323.6 |
299.9 |
-5.0 |
-7.3 |
Singapore |
270.8 |
244.1 |
34.1 |
34.1 |
-9.9 |
0.0 |
Sri Lanka |
1493 |
1585.2 |
258.6 |
305.5 |
6.2 |
18.1 |
Taiwan Province of China |
2185 |
2103.9 |
308.3 |
283.6 |
-3.7 |
-8.0 |
Thailand |
2071.7 |
2198.2 |
314.1 |
372.8 |
6.1 |
18.7 |
Vietnam |
2484.3 |
2719.7 |
361.8 |
430.2 |
9.5 |
18.9 |
What needs to be
noted is that the displacement of US production, to
the extent that it occurred, is a sign that the US
has not adequately restructured its industry during
the long years of protection resorted to for this
very purpose. The protection afforded to developed
country textile production with the aim of restructuring
those industries began in the 1961, when the Long
Term Agreement on textiles was signed. That agreement
provided the developed countries with a 10-year respite,
during which they were expected to either phase out
a part of their uncompetitive textile production,
"burdened" by high wages, or modernise their
textile industries to render them competitive.
The promise to do away with protection in ten years
did not materialise. Protection was continued under
the Multi-Fibre Agreement, which was once more scrutinised
for phase-out under the Uruguay Round Agreement of
1994. But even under that agreement, the phase-out
of quotas was back-loaded, with quotas on close to
half of global textile trade kept in place till January
1, 2005. It is well known that most developed countries
first lifted quotas on items of less relevance to
developing country trade, reserving true liberalisation
till the beginning of 2005.
What the first-quarter surge in textile exports to
the US indicates is that despite 45 years of protection
expressly justified by the need to restructure the
industry, the US has not done so, unlike countries
such as the UK whose dependence on textiles during
the early stages of their industrialisation was even
greater. But the US is not the only culprit. Even
countries in the EU (such as France and Italy) are
using the US resistance to the Chinese export surge
as the basis for a demand for greater protection for
their own textile production. The European Union's
trade commissioner, Peter Mandelson, has been resisting
pressure to impose restrictions on Chinese textile
imports, on the grounds that the available evidence
of market disruption is inconclusive and could not
justify curbs for the time being. However, his ambivalent
postures, resulting from differences within the Community,
suggest that the EU too might resort to import curbs.
Responding to calls from countries like Sweden not
to impose such curbs, since that would amount to protectionism,
Mandelson declared: "We should not confuse protection
with protectionism."
All this controversy arises despite efforts by China
to dampen the growth of its textile exports since
January 2005 to temper the reaction to likely export
increases. In December 2004, China imposed export
tariffs of Rmb0.2-Rmb0.3 per item in some cases and
Rmb0.5 per kilogramme in others in response to concerns
in the US and Europe that Chinese textile exports
might surge following the expiry of quotas on January
1. Now, China is contemplating further export tariffs.
Expectations are that China might raise export tariffs
by as much as Rmb2-Rmb4 per piece. Such action is
being contemplated despite the danger that Chinese
exporters are likely to be badly hit, because prices
for garment orders are fixed several months before
shipment.
China's need to bend over backwards to placate the
US results from three factors. First, China's own
dependence on the US market for exports that have
become a major engine for its growth. Second, the
huge trade and current account deficit on the US balance
of payments, which is resulting in a depreciation
of the dollar and rising the spectre of a financial
crash and global recession. Third, the huge US trade
deficit with China that the former wants to reduce
by getting China to revalue its currency. The message
is clear, if developing countries record a deficit
on their balance of payments it is their problem and
a reflection of their mismanagement. If the US records
a deficit on it external account that is everybody's
problem and a reflection of a global "imbalance"
that needs correction.
Unfortunately, imposing
curbs on Chinese textile imports into the US or the
EU may not resolve the problem either of unemployment
in the US and EU textile industries or the deficit
on the US trade account. It would merely serve to
increase textile exports from other developing countries
to the US and EU. But the fact that this could be
used to divide developing country exporters and win
the support from some of them in the battle against
China may suit the US and EU. It helps win allies
in the battle to force China to turn inwards rather
than grow on the basis of burgeoning exports. Globalisation
is good only when the USand perhaps the EU reaps its
benefita. If that does not happen, protectionism or
voluntary export restraint is the preferred alternative.
|