Themes > Economic Briefs       Print           
Print this article
Diversity, Space, Learning, Regionalism : Notes and Reflection *
Norman Girvan

A new development paradigm should recognise diversity of circumstances, provide space for policy experimentation, and validate learning as integral to development. Regionalism can be an important support strategy for such a paradigm. The rationale for regionalism in this context lies in its potential to strengthen the bargaining power of the regional grouping vis-à-vis the global system in order to bolster the claim for the recognition of diversity and enhance the space for experimentation, while enriching the learning process through exchange of experience. This concept note poses questions related to this theme and that of the panel.

Universalism
A notable aspect of the neo-liberal paradigm is its claim to universalism, i.e. a single over-arching explanation of the way economies work and a single prescriptive principle for good policies in time and place. The market economy is both abstracted from society and assumed to be dominant over society. An extension of the paradigm conflates market economy with political democracy and good governance.

As opposed to this there is a tradition which I characterise as historical/institutional/structural (HIS). Economies are seen as rooted in history and social structures and are the products of evolution over time. Inherited institutions and structures are not a straight-jacket for the present, but they do condition the responses of economic agents to policy instruments. Hence what "works" for one country at one time may work differently in another country at the same time or in the same country at a different time. Accordingly, there is no universally applicable prescriptive principle regarding the appropriate role of market and state. There is no substitute for a close and detailed examination of specific circumstances, informed by a sense of humility.

The problem with this approach, of course, is that it is messy. It does not easily lend itself to formalisation and the kind of rigor that is permitted by mathematical theorems. And the room for subjective interpretation is wide. But is our concern with "truth" (however defined) or with convenience? One is reminded of Sen's observation to the effect that it is better to be partially right than to be exactly wrong. One also suspects that the influence of formalism may be as much about power relations in the production and reproduction of knowledge as it is about concern with rigor. One of the characteristics of formalism is that it allows ideology to masquerade as science. The degree of abstraction is so great and the assumptions underlying the theorems so deeply buried that the ideology of the market takes on a neutral appearance. And since advanced mathematical analysis is accessible only to a few, its practitioners are hardly ever called upon to justify their assumptions and value judgements, let alone held accountable for their policy prescriptions.

The proposition that a HIS is not amenable to formalisation is also questionable. It needs to be investigated. A better way to pose the question is, what are the appropriate criteria by which any analysis of the human economy is to be validated? What would constitute acceptable procedures for investigation, the generation and validation of propositions, the derivation of policy prescriptions, and the monitoring and evaluation of their application? Surely formalism will be part of the answer. But once again I refer to the need for humility. We are dealing with the livelihoods and welfare of people, indeed of their very lives. Recent history is so replete with examples of the terrible costs of the inappropriate application of mistaken theories-both of the right and the left-that it should give cause for sober reflection and contemplation.

It is here, perhaps, that universalism does have a role to play. If trans-paradigm intercourse is to go beyond a dialogue of the deaf, then there should be common agreement on rules of procedure. If analysis of the specific is to minimise the room for subjective judgement and interpretation, then there ought to be commonly accepted methods of investigation and verification. But there cannot be any final word on this. What is universally accepted will itself be the subject of continued experimentation, debate and enrichment. Universalisation, therefore, may be seen as continuous and unending process of expansion of consensus on method. Basic to the process are recognition of diversity, mutual cross-cultural respect, and rejection of dogma in all its forms.

We know, of course, that what I have called the HIS approach has a long and distinguished progeny. It dates back at least to Adam Smith through the 19th century political economists (including Marx) to the 20th century with Polanyi, institutional economics, economic anthropology and so on. We also know that at a certain point this tradition became marginalized from mainstream economics. It is now being revisited as a result of the collapse of Sovietism and the equally disastrous policy failures of neo-liberalism. So there is now a window of opportunity, which if fully utilised, can become a means of escape from the intellectual ghetto.

Learning
A note here on learning. In economics the subject has been treated mainly, if not exclusively, in the context of productivity growth, technical change and technology transfer. The focus, therefore, is the firm level. But what about social learning for policy analysis? What I am proposing here is that societies, like individuals and organizations, can learn to do better; but only if they organise themselves consciously for the task. This goes beyond the learning that comes from repetition and mastery of a given task, a la learning curve. It embraces the elements of trial and error, policy experimentation, evaluation, further policy innovation, and so on in a continuous loop.

This is a highly idealised, if not utopian, model of development and change. In the real world societies have interest groups that fight for their own advantage. Still, is it not an ideal worth opposing to universalistic claims of policy prescriptions often advanced by the IFIs? Certainly, to this writer it suggests a healthier model for development "partnerships" between the north and the south. The goal of partnerships, then, should be to support and facilitate indigenous social learning for the attainment of mutually agreed development objectives.

Regionalism
What role, then, for regionalism? To begin with, regionalism comes in different shapes and forms. "Open" regionalism was invented as part of the model of neo-liberal globalisation. Its alternative is neither "closed" regionalism nor an outright rejection of globalisation. I have argued that, especially for small countries, the ideal role of regionalism is to strengthen the bargaining position of the group vis-a-vis the global system and to enlarge the space for policy autonomy within the region. The two are closely linked, insofar as the new dispensation of the WTO and regional agreements (FTAA, ACP-EU, etc) is for trade agreements to extend deeply into the sphere of domestic policy and institutions.

How can regionalism help? First, through functional cooperation in extra-regional relations. The pooling of bargaining power and negotiation resources in global agreements in trade and finance is one area. Key issues here are special and differential treatment in trade agreements, timing and sequencing of trade liberalisation, debt, conditionality, regulation of international finance, and IFI governance. Functional cooperation will aim to secure outcomes more favourable to LDCs by preserving and expanding the internal space for policy-making and social learning.

Second, through intra-regional functional cooperation in the development effort. This goes beyond the liberalisation of intra-regional markets that is the prime objective of open regionalism. For instance, a regional group can cooperate in strategic planning for participation in international markets, in industrial policy to build up firm-based technological and managerial capabilities among national firms, in socio-economic economic policies to empower the poor, in science and technology and research and development, and in higher education. The greater the technology, capital and skilled resource-intensity of these activities involved in responding to the challenges of the global economy, the greater the potential returns from resource pooling through functional cooperation.

* Prepared for Annual Conference for Development and Change Antigua, Guatemala, 28-30 July, 2003 Session II: Rethinking the role of the State, Markets and Institutions in the Era of Economic Globalization

October 1, 2003.

 

© International Development Economics Associates 2003