The
''Peoples' Plan campaign'' in the
Indian state of Kerala, which led to the devolution
of nearly a third of the Plan outlay of the State
to Local Self Government Institutions (LSGIs) to spend
on projects of their choice, has of late generated
much controversy. Many have even argued that ''decentralization''
is a part of the imperialist agenda and that the Left's
adoption of it represents a capitulation (which can
be explained only through the ''erroneous''
activities and understanding of some leading Comrades).
This entire line of criticism however misses a basic
point, namely that the ''decentralization''
proposed by the Left, propagated through the Peoples'
Plan campaign, and implemented during the years of
LDF rule is fundamentally different from the ''decentralization''
promoted by the World Bank and other imperialist agencies.
While the ''decentralization'' agenda of
the Left is a means of carrying class-struggle forward,
of buttressing the class-strength of the rural poor
by developing institutions where they can, in principle,
assert themselves directly and hence more effectively,
the ''decentralization'' promoted by the
imperialist agencies has precisely the opposite objective,
of blunting class-struggle, of encouraging a scenario
of ''obedient-and-supplicant-villagers-being-patronized-by-NGOs'',
and of substituting the concept of the ''Rights''
of the people by the concept of ''Self-Help''.
In pushing their agenda, it is in the interests of
the imperialist agencies to pretend as if there is
no difference between their programme and the Left
programme. But for that very reason it is essential
for the Left to emphasize in every possible manner
the difference between the two agendas, to highlight
the specificity of the imperialist agenda, if it is
to defeat the latter.
I
It is a deliberate ploy of imperialism to borrow
concepts from the Left and incorporate them into its
own lexicon after giving them a different meaning.
This habit of borrowing concepts serves many purposes:
first, the analytical depth that is usually associated
with any Left concept is mistakenly attributed to
the imperialist concept as well and imparts a prestige
to imperialist theory; secondly, since the same concept
is used by the enemies of the Left as by the Left
itself, it creates confusion in Left ranks, and blunts
a basic weapon of the latter, namely theoretical clarity;
thirdly, by creating fuzziness around basic concepts
imperialism seeks to destroy clarity of thinking in
society as a whole, which helps to establish and perpetuate
its hegemony.
Consider an example. Terms like "structure",
"structural change", "structuralism",
and "structural reforms" were originally
developed in the ranks of the Left as a critique of
imperialist theory. As against the standard imperialist
view that the free market was the panacea for the
ills of the third world, the Left advanced the theory
that the third world needed a rupture with the structures
inherited from its colonial and semi-colonial past,
via land reforms, via de-linking from the imperialist-dominated
world market, via building up the public sector as
a bulwark against metropolitan capital, and via a
rapid process of planned industrialization. This was
so clear an intellectual divide that the term "structure"
was as much a short-hand for Left thinking as "market"
was for the Right. And yet today the term "structural
adjustment" has become a central part of Fund-Bank
theory; it is given a meaning that is precisely the
opposite of what it originally meant within the Left
lexicon, namely "opening" the economy to
the free play of the so-called market forces. Imperialist
agencies simply took over a Left concept and used
it for their own purposes after giving it a different
meaning.
The same is happening today to the concept of "decentralization",
which has been, for a very long time, and particularly
in India for the last quarter of a century, i.e. since
1977 when the Left Front government came to power
in West Bengal, an integral part of the Left lexicon.
This was long before the so-called "economic
reforms" began and the Fund and the Bank started
strutting around on the Indian scene. But soon they,
and other imperialist agencies like the ADB and DFID,
started talking about "decentralization"
as if they had invented the term, and giving it a
fundamentally different meaning from what it had as
part of the Left lexicon. So successful has been their
ploy that today, as mentioned earlier, many who claim
to owe allegiance to the Left have actually started
demanding that the Left should have nothing to do
with decentralization which is an imperialist concept
and hence a part of an imperialist conspiracy. This
is "liquidationism" at the level of theory.
Instead of exposing the imperialist game of taking
over Left concepts and exploiting their legitimacy
for its own nefarious ends, this perception actually
accepts imperialist claims of having authored the
concepts themselves, and abandons legitimate democratic
issues on the absurd ground that if imperialism is
talking "about the same thing" then they
cannot be legitimate democratic issues. The whole
point however is that imperialism is not talking about
the same thing.
My purpose in this paper is to distinguish between
imperialism's concept of decentralization and the
Left concept which, as already noted, is far older
and rooted in its own philosophical tradition. I shall
not however, for reasons of space, be going into the
whole gamut of Left thinking on this question. I shall
confine myself only to the concept of decentralized
planning as conceived of and practised by the LDF
government in Kerala, examine its specificities, and
show the difference between this practice and the
one advocated by the imperialist agencies.
II
Two basic questions can be asked about Kerala's "decentralization"
experiment. First, what is its relationship with planning?
And secondly, what is its link with class-struggle
in the countryside? In this section I shall address
the first of these questions, keeping the second to
the next section. Section IV discusses the contrast
between this "decentralization" and the
imperialist concept. The last section contains some
concluding observations.
Even traditionally, i.e. prior to the intrusion of
the imperialist concept, the term "decentralization"
had been used in different contexts to mean several
different things. To examine the specificity of the
Kerala experiment therefore let me begin by distinguishing
between some of these traditional meanings.
There are at least four different senses in which
the term has been used in the economic literature.
The first is decentralization as in a capitalist market
economy, where there are a number of separate decision-makers,
such as firms and consumers, and the overall functioning
of the economy, its performance in any period and
its dynamics over time, is a resultant of these dispersed
individual decisions. By contrast a planned economy
in its classical meaning is supposed to function on
the basis of centralized decision-making. A comparison
between the two systems of decision-making used to
be a common theme in economics at one time, and the
case for the superiority of the centralized system
was argued on the grounds that it overcame the "anarchy
of the market" to which Marx, and Keynes, in
their different ways had drawn attention[1].
(Maurice Dobb and Michael Kalecki were perhaps the
most persuasive presenters of this argument).
The other three senses in which the term has been
used refer essentially to the context of a planned
economy itself, but one which despite being planned
is not centralized in the sense of being a "command
economy". The second meaning of the term has
to do with decentralization as an arrangement for
information flow in a planned economy, such as was
proposed famously by Oskar Lange and later by Kornai
and Liptak. Of course the Lange vision of decentralization,
and that of Kornai-Liptak, referred not to actual
decentralization but merely to a procedure of central
planning, to the operation, as Joan Robinson was to
put it, of a "pseudo-market" in a planned
economy, so that the plan gets finalized on the basis
of a two-way flow of information between the central
planner and the individual enterprises.
The idea is the following. The Central Planner announces
a set of prices (these prices are only announced,
they do not actually rule in any market), and on the
basis of these prices the enterprises inform the Planner
how much they would like to produce in order to maximize
the enterprise profits. Since the sum of these output
decisions would differ from what the Planner might
wish to have as the Plan target, it would then announce
a set of revised prices; and so the ''iteration'',
i.e. the to-and-fro movement of information, would
continue until a final Plan is prepared. The sole
advantage of this ''iteration'' proposal is that the
Planner does not need to have detailed knowledge of
all the resources and raw materials available with
each and every enterprise[2].
Even though this ''iteration'' is supposed
to occur only through a "pseudo-market",
i.e. only through an exchange of information to which
there is no actual market counterpart, one could in
principle even make this ''iteration'' occur
in actual practice. The Central Planner could announces
a set of prices, leave it to enterprises to produce
amounts they like at these prices, and hold unsold
amounts as stocks. In all cases where the stocks were
large, the prices could be lowered and where they
were small, prices could be increased, and so on.
There would not then be one overall final plan, but
a series of adjustments on an initial blue-print,
approximating towards but never actually reaching
a final consistent document. Room would have to be
made in such a case through appropriate institutional
provisions (e.g. larger inventories etc.) for the
realization of such an approximate plan, but a planned
economy of this sort could still function in a manner
that curbs on the whole the anarchy of capitalism.
The third sense in which the term decentralization
has been used is in the context of the view that the
unit over which planning is done is not the country's
economy as a whole but the economies of particular
parts of it. Here we have not a change in the model
of central planning, but a splitting up of the units
over which the central plans are formulated. (And
if we are talking not of a fully-planned economy but
of a mixed or partially-planned economy, such as India
was in its dirigiste phase, then "decentralization"
would refer to a reduction in the size of the unit
over which such partial planning is done.) An idea
was current among several progressive thinkers in
the country at one time that, barring a few areas
such as defence, communications, and foreign policy
etc., the rest of the functions of the government,
including in particular development, should be undertaken
by the State governments. Whether the Centre makes
actual resources available to the States for this
purpose, or resource-raising powers are themselves
transferred to the States, this perception of "decentralization"
amounts to a change not in the relation between the
plan and enterprises but in the unit over which planning,
of whatever variety, occurs.
The fourth concept of "decentralization"
refers to a situation where, if an individual or collective
unit is to be the beneficiary of a set of projects
in a particular sphere, then they should be allowed
to finalize the precise mix of such projects. This
is nothing else but an extension of the principle
that when it comes to certain kinds of goods, it is
better that individuals (or families) are given the
cash to purchase these goods[3],
rather than these goods being made directly available
to them, a principle that often goes under the grandiose
(and, in capitalist conditions, misleading) title
of "consumers' sovereignty". In certain
spheres in other words, "users' sovereignty"
should be respected.
The last two meanings of the term "decentralization"
might appear to be too close for drawing any worthwhile
distinction between them, but there is a significant
difference in "quantity" between the two
cases which almost amounts to a difference in "quality".
I perceive these four cases in the following terms
respectively: "decentralization as anarchy",
"decentralization as iteration", "decentralization
as multiplication" and "decentralization
as users' sovereignty". Of course in practice
these different cases come not in pure form but often
jumbled up, and neat pigeon-holing of any actual case
of "decentralization" into any one of these
cases may be difficult; nonetheless this distinction
is useful for assessing the implications of particular
cases of decentralization. For instance it would be
grossly erroneous to see the Kerala case of "decentralization"
through "peoples' planning" as engendering
either "anarchy" or "multiplication"
or mere "iteration". It is quite clearly
of the fourth kind. It does not in principle negate
planning (even of the sort we have in India); rather
it is based on invoking, implicitly, the concept of
"users' sovereignty" as justification for
the devolution of plan funds to LSGIs for undertaking
certain kinds of projects within an overall plan.
Two caveats have to be entered here. First, if a plan
is to have consistency, i.e. various commodity balances
have to be satisfied, then the fact that the mix of
projects is left to the individual LSGIs would have
problematical implications. Flow excess demands and
flow excess supplies of particular commodities would
arise on account of the fact that the decisions of
the individual LSGIs are not co-ordinated ex ante.
But this problem (as in the second case discussed
above of real-life ''iterative'' planning)
can be resolved through the holding of appropriate
inventories. Secondly, if the LSGIs are to be not
merely plan-fund-using institutions but are to take
some initiative in mobilizing resources of their own
and using these for their own purposes, or even taking
on productive roles and using the proceeds obtained
from doing so for their own purposes, then these activities
and the expenditures generated on account of them
would constitute "add-ons" to the basic
plan of the economy. These "add-ons", since
they are not based on any ex ante co-ordination, could
upset the basic balance of the plan by creating ex
ante flow excess demands and supplies. Once again
however the problem can be handled by making prior
provision for such contingencies through the appropriate
provision of inventories or by maintaining a higher
level of planned excess capacity in the productive
sectors within the framework of the plan itself.
It follows then that the "peoples' planning"
experiment of Kerala, while it entails "decentralization",
in the sense that the budgeted amount earmarked as
expenditure on certain items in the plan, such as
rural infrastructure, is handed over to the LSGIs
in order to reflect better the preferences of the
users, does not mean a negation of planning. On the
contrary, it can be defended on the grounds of "users'
sovereignty". True, the amount handed over to
the LSGIs has been fixed as a percentage of the total
plan outlay rather than being independently determined
on the basis of the estimated expenditure under the
relevant heads, but the figure for this percentage
itself has been arrived at by considering the approximate
proportion of expenditure actually incurred in the
past on these items. Hence the "users' sovereignty"
argument is not undermined by the fact of the devolution
being fixed as a percentage of plan funds.
The additional merit of the Kerala experiment consists
of the fact that "users' sovereignty" is
sought to be exercised through collective bodies directly
or through their democratically elected representatives.
This brings me however to the second question that
can be asked about Kerala's decentralization experiment.
III
To see LSGIs as being uncontaminated by class-struggle
would be an idealistic error, reminiscent of the old
"village community" hypothesis of Baden
Powell. They contain class contradictions, and the
mode of use of resources devolved to them under the
decentralization agenda occurs via class struggle
(whose intensity however varies depending on the degree
of antagonism that is immanent in the class configuration).
But even if there was no decentralization and the
mode of use of plan resources for these particular
items was bureaucratically determined, then the outcome
would still have been determined by class struggle,
but class struggle over shaping bureaucratic preference.
In short, decentralization neither does away with,
nor engenders, class-struggle in the countryside which
exists anyway and is a fact of life.
The impact of decentralization on this pre-existing
fact of life can be three-fold. First, it provides
an opportunity to the rural poor to assert themselves
in a way that bureaucratic decision-making would not
have made possible. True, the bureaucratic outcome
may turn out in many instances to be more "humane",
but it leaves no scope for the rural poor to realize
their subjectivity in this domain. For this very reason
however the need for organizing the rural poor to
assert themselves becomes paramount, and this need
can be fulfilled only through the intervention of
a political Party. The idea of Party-less LSGIs in
other words represents a throwback to the idealism
of the "village community" concept. This
greater ability on the part of the rural poor to assert
themselves would necessarily come into conflict with
the prevailing property relations in the countryside
(except in situations where radical land redistribution
has already been carried out), but that only underscores
the fact that "decentralization" is a part
of the dialectics of class struggle. It is not some
"ideal" arrangement at which society can
remain frozen, but part of the process of carrying
forward the dialectics of class struggle, which does
not necessarily mean of course a state of continuous
violent conflict. (In fact the organization of the
rural poor by a political Party committed to their
emancipation is a means of controlling violent conflict).
Secondly, it provides a legacy for the construction
of a better society. Any socialist society must build
on the institutions bequeathed to it by the pre-existing
society. Indeed a part of the reason for the excessive
centralization, and the accompanying authoritarianism,
that prevailed in the earlier socialist societies
lay in the absence of any representative democratic
institutions in these societies prior to the emergence
of socialism on which the latter could build its foundations.
In that sense the decentralization experiment, by
empowering elected bodies, puts life into a whole
range of institutions on the basis of which a future
society can be built.
This argument must be sharply distinguished from the
so-called ''social capital'' argument. First,
we are talking here of representative political institutions,
not clubs or addas, or religious gatherings, or the
innumerable instances of social interaction among
individuals that the so-called ''social capital''
theory picks up for celebration. The flourishing of
such instances of social interaction is not only perfectly
compatible with the putting in place of thoroughly
non-representative political institutions, but has
actually accompanied, throughout the history of modern
India, the most bizarre attempts at the denial of
political rights to large masses of the people. And
secondly, we are talking about representative political
institutions through which the conflict between classes
plays itself out, not about institutions sans such
conflict, and hence about institutions defending the
status quo, which typically constitute the desideratum
of ''Social Capital'' theory.
Thirdly, it trains the people in the art of book-keeping,
in the art of responsible financial management etc.
which constitutes another legacy for the future, apart
from strengthening even the existing system of parliamentary
democracy. One of the weaknesses of revolutionary
Russia that Lenin had highlighted was the absence
of knowledge of "bourgeois management principles".
The overcoming of this absence, even partially, would
go a long way towards providing the basis for the
construction of a socialist society in the future.
While there is no conflict between the perspective
of class struggle leading to the creation of a socialist
society and the empowerment of the LSGIs within our
prevailing social order through greater devolution
of resources (just as there is no conflict between
such devolution and the erection of a planned economy),
the opposite error can also be committed, namely the
the mistake of treating the LSGIs as if they already
constitute the organs of popular rule. There is an
ocean of difference between LSGIs within a bourgeois-landlord
order and "communes" in a socialist order.
While the latter can be built, looking at the matter
in very general terms, on the foundations provided
by the former, the vast gulf between the two must
not be overlooked.
IV
Let me now come to the difference between Kerala-style
"decentralized planning" and the imperialist
concept of decentralization. This latter has no theoretical
basis, and hence is different from any of the four
senses in which the term has been used in economic
literature, to which reference was made earlier. Indeed
it is never explicitly set out as one coherent vision;
on the contrary, there is a certain (deliberate) fuzziness
about it which allows it to mean all things to all
people[4]. One therefore has to cull
out the main features of this concept of decentralization
not so much from theoretical writings on the subject
as from the practices enforced on particular State
governments, such as Andhra Pradesh, which have accepted
the tutelage of imperialist agencies. There is also
an additional problem, namely there are different
imperialist agencies lording over different States
and over different sectors, which may make generalizations
difficult. We can discern nonetheless a degree of
consensus among them over conceptual issues, on the
basis of which we can reconstruct the imperialist
concept of decentralization.
This consensus arises above all from the fact that
all of them see ''decentralization'', even
in the sense of devolution of powers and resources
to lower tiers of administration, as an aid to a ''free-market''
economy. For instance the World Bank puts forward
its fuzzy views on decentralization in a section of
the World Development Report 2002 which is titled
Building Institutions for Markets. In other words
''decentralization'' for imperialist agencies
is not a matter of relocating powers, resources and
functions within an activist State (in matters of
investment), but of building an apparatus that fits
into the ''neo-liberal'' paradigm.
It is not surprising in this context that the following
four propositions regarding decentralization are more
or less common to all the imperialist agencies. First,
while they talk about Gram Sabhas they invariably
see the Gram Sabhas as being presided over, and led
by, not the elected representatives of the people,
but by outside officials. Their perspective in short
is not one of strengthening representative institutions
in the countryside, but of providing a democratic
veneer to a process of essentially bureaucratic decision-making
(which can always be manipulated to fall in line with
their wishes). Secondly, they see the major tasks
of the LSGIs being carried out through a number of
Committees, consisting not of elected representatives
of the people but of ''experts'' and corporate-NGOs,
and these are to be allowed to enter into direct negotiations
with funding agencies for loans for particular projects.
Thirdly, their emphasis is on ''Self-Help''
groups rather than the ''Right'' of the
LSGIs to a share of the Plan funds of the State government.
To be sure, Self-Help groups can be of assistance
to the rural poor under certain circumstances, but
what is noteworthy about the perspective of these
agencies is the overwhelming emphasis on these groups
to the exclusion of the LSGIs' ''Right''
to Plan Funds. And finally, whenever any infrastructure
projects are undertaken at the local level, these
agencies insist on the imposition of ''user charges'',
i.e. their exclusive emphasis is on the adoption of
the commercial principle even in the matter of peoples'
access to basic amenities.
What these four propositions amount to is a negation
of representative institutions, a negation of all
political activity, reflective of class struggle in
the countryside, in local government, a negation of
''Rights'' of the people to Plan Funds as
users of infrastructure, and the erection of a mai-baap
ethos, reminiscent of the old colonial administration
trying to wear a paternalist cloak, with imperialist-aided
NGOs being presented as the benevolent patrons of
the countryside.
In short, this concept of ''decentralization''
visualizes a substitution of the State by a set of
NGOs in the implementation of local projects, including
especially social sector projects, the funds for which,
whether drawn from the State budget or from foreign
donors, are expended through these NGOs. Putting it
differently, imperialist "decentralization"
is concerned neither with a particular model of planning,
nor even a mere substitution of the free market for
planning, but with establishing a direct access of
imperialist agencies to the Indian countryside through
a bunch of NGOs who are in no way accountable to the
people.
What is often missed by those who do not see the difference
between Kerala-style decentralization and the World
Bank concept is that the LSGIs are also a part of
the State apparatus. Transferring certain responsibilities
to the LSGIs therefore is tantamount to a redistribution
of responsibility within the State structure, but
a redistribution that has the aim of enforcing greater
accountability of the State. The concept of "users'
sovereignty" invoked above was linked essentially
to this greater accountability. Such "sovereignty"
could be exercised only because of the introduction
of greater accountability on the State for which decentralization
was a means. To be sure, the sheer fact of decentralization
would not bring about all these changes; on the contrary,
in regions where the poor are unorganized decentralization
could have the opposite effect of strengthening the
local oppressors, who, prior to decentralization,
might have been kept in check through the actions
of "benevolent" elements of the bureaucracy.
But, in principle, democratic decentralization is
to be preferred, no matter how unsatisfactory its
immediate results (this point of course is not relevant
for Kerala) , because it enforces greater accountability
on the State and restores greater subjectivity to
the people.
Imperialist decentralization however has nothing to
do with the subjectivity of the people, even when
the people are consulted on their preferences, since
it operates not through statutory institutions but
through voluntary organizations. Indeed its very objective
is to reduce the scope for the operations of statutory
institutions, and their replacement by voluntary agencies
which are either directly funded by imperialist donors,
or are funded from the State budget which in turn
has come to depend heavily on imperialist sources
for funding social sector expenditures. In short,
World Bank decentralization refers essentially to
a withdrawal of the State from the social sector,
while the aim of decentralized planning was not a
withdrawal but greater accountability of an activist
State.
Enfeebling the third world State, even the third world
bourgeois State, breaking down whatever relative autonomy
it may have vis-à-vis imperialism, and reducing
it to the status of either a collaborationist or a
client or even a puppet State, is a persistent objective
of imperialism. This is because a relatively autonomous
third world State can act as a bulwark against imperialist
domination. This enfeeblement is brought about through
a number of different instruments. For instance the
imposition of neo-liberal economic policies necessarily
results in an accentuation of the fiscal crisis of
the third world State, which is then used to induct
direct funding of social sector expenditures by imperialist
agencies (the DPEP is a classic example of this and
there are designated "World Bank districts"
in India where this important social sector expenditure
has become the responsibility of the Bank). The Bank's
notion of "decentralization" is a part of
this project of enfeebling the third world State,
and is therefore well-integrated into the plethora
of neo-liberal policies. One aspect of these policies
which has been well recognized is the withdrawal of
the State from an autonomous active role in the social
sector in favour of the market; the other aspect which
has received less attention however is the withdrawal
of the State from an activist role in this sector
in favour of imperialist agencies which then penetrate
the countryside both directly and through imperialist-funded
NGOs.
V
It follows from what has
just been said that, Kerala-style decentralization,
far from being indistinguishable from imperialist
decentralization, actually faces a threat from the
latter, or at any rate from the package of policies
of which the latter is an integral part. The real
problem with Kerala-style decentralization in the
present context lies in other words in the fact that
it tends to get undermined not because of its own
failings but from outside: from the pursuit of the
neo-liberal agenda by the country's government, and
from its efforts to push neo-liberal "reforms"
on the State governments.
The neo-liberal dispensation necessarily implies an
accentuation of the fiscal travails of the Central
government, which the latter in turn passes down to
the State governments. It is noteworthy that during
the nineties the ratio of the Central government's
tax revenue to the GDP went down while that of the
State governments went up, and yet the latter were
afflicted with acute fiscal crises by the beginning
of the new century. It is not just one or two States
that are facing fiscal difficulties but virtually
every State, though to differing degrees. Reduced
transfers from the Centre, and the pay-hikes in the
wake of the Central government's acceptance of the
Fifth Pay Commission report, have of course played
their part in precipitating this fiscal crisis of
the State governments. But a very important contributing
factor has been the sharp increase in interest rates
on State government debt.
The Central government's own borrowing rates have
gone up with the end of the ad hoc Treasury Bills
route, which came with neo-liberalism. What is more,
the Centre has deliberately, gratuitously, and quite
unwarrantedly, jacked up the rates of interest it
charges on loans to the State governments, and used
the debt-trap to which it has pushed the State governments
to impose neo-liberal policies on them. It has even
used the offices of the Eleventh Finance Commission
to impose "reforms" on States as a pre-condition
for their obtaining funds that are due to them anyway
under the Constitution[5]!
With the State governments starved of funds, the LSGIs
too find themselves short of resources. No worthwhile
"local level planning" is possible under
these circumstances. Besides, when the State governments
are short of funds, they turn to international agencies
like the ADB or the World Bank for financing investment
projects in rural areas which they themselves would
have otherwise done[6]. These agencies
in turn have their own ways of allocating their funds
between projects, and monitoring the use of their
funds in rural infrastructure, which either preclude
the involvement of the LSGIs or give them at best
a token role[7]. A vibrant programme
of decentralization, which can lead to the greater
assertiveness of the rural poor, thus runs counter
in a fundamental sense to the trajectory of development
of a neo-liberal economic regime.
References
Dobb, M.H. (1969) Wefare
Economics and the Economics of Socialism, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge.
The World Bank (1997) ''The State in a Changing World'',
World Development Report 1997, Oxford University Press,
Oxford.
The World Bank (2000) ''Entering the Twenty-first
Century'', World Development Report 1999-2000, Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
The World Bank (2002) ''Building Institutions for
Markets'', World Development Report 2002, Oxford University
Press, Oxford.
[1] Keynes who
was a liberal bourgeois economist aware of the fact
that capitalism was subject to anarchy, wanted to
preserve capitalism against the socialist threat by
reforming it so that the basic property relations
remained unchanged but there was "socialization
of investment" through State intervention.
[2] For a discussion of these issues
see Maurice Dobb (1969).
[3] For a discussion of this principle
as well as where it should not apply see Dobb (1969),
Chapter 10.
[4] See for instance The World Bank
(1997, 2000, 2002).
[5] A dissenting note by Dr.Amaresh
Bagchi, a member of the Eleventh Finance Commission,
took strong exception to this procedure adopted by
the Commission.
[6] This itself is the result of fallacious
reasoning on the part of the Central government. Since
no foreign exchange is required for such investments,
borrowing from domestic banks which are flush with
funds and would put very little "conditionalities"
would have no worse consequences than borrowing from
these agencies which do insist on "conditionalities".
But the Central government is quite liberal in allowing
the States to borrow from these agencies, and charges
much higher interest rates to the states than these
agencies do, while it is very strict in allowing States
to borrow from domestic banks.
[7] When local agencies are to be
involved in the implementation of such projects, then,
as mentioned earlier, NGOs, or parallel institutions
to the LSGIs as in Andhra Pradesh, seem to be the
preferred option.
April 15, 2004.
|