On
22 December 2001, following the defeat of the Taliban
by a coalition of US and Northern Alliance forces,
an interim administration under Hamid Karzai mandated
from above by the Bonn peace agreement took charge
of Afghanistan. Being a relatively small, landlocked
and poor country that has experienced civil strife
for more than two decades starting 1979, with different
degrees of external involvement, Afghanistan's economy
at the time of formation of the interim administration
was both backward and disintegrated. With 85 per cent
of its population reportedly dependent on agriculture
and 53 per cent of the GDP estimated as originating
in the agricultural, livestock and forestry sectors,
as compared with 28 per cent in light industry, 8
per cent in trade and 6 per cent in construction,
the economy in 2002 was structurally in an early stage
of development. Extremely rough estimates quoted by
the Asian Development Bank suggest that in 2002, Afghanistan's
GDP amounted to $4.4 billion, which implied a GDP
per capita of an abysmally low $170 per head.
These figures, however, could exaggerate the level
of backwardness implicit in the initial conditions
from which Afghanistan must begin its process of reconstruction
and revival. Two factors have contributed to the high
'aggregate poverty' indicated by a per capita income
that is less than half of the international poverty
norm of a dollar per day per head by 2001. The first
is the war that led to the ouster of the Taliban.
An earlier estimate, also quoted by the ADB, relating
to 1989, placed Afghanistan's GDP at a much higher
$6.9 billion and its per capita income at around $300.
The situation could have further improved in the years
following 1989, since reports indicate that at least
in regions fully occupied by the Taliban, economic
conditions were stable during the early and the mid-1990s.
Underlying the subsequent massive contraction of the
economy was the war that devastated the limited infrastructure
of the country, triggered the exodus of more than
3 million refugees to Pakistan, Iran and elsewhere
and displaced a large number of people within the
country. This disrupted or even brought to a standstill
much of the economic activity within the country.
A corollary of this role of the late 1990s war in
worsening economic condition is that a concerted reconstruction
effort focused on quick-impact projects combined with
the observed large-scale return of refugees to Afghanistan,
could ensure a sharp rise in GDP and per capita income
to levels in the early 1990s.
Secondly, nature too added to the woes of an already
war-ravaged economy, with protracted drought conditions
that began in 1999 and lasted till 2001. Again according
to estimates made by the international community,
in this case the World Bank, crop production was halved
and livestock herds substantially depleted, making
the situation in 2002 as desperate as it was. According
to a March 2002 survey by the FAO, the livestock population
in the country declined by 60 per cent due to the
distress selling of livestock herds in the summer
and autumn of 2001 triggered by the persisting conditions
of drought. The crucial role of drought in worsening
economic conditions is revealed by an FAO and World
Food Programme estimate which states that agricultural
production in 2002 rose by 82 per cent, following
better rainfall conditions. However, even in that
year cereal production is estimated at 4 per cent
below its 1998 level. Given the importance of agriculture
for employment and GDP in the economy, these figures
suggest that the rough GDP estimates relating to 2002
may be exaggerating the poor state of the economy.
These real factors that perhaps exaggerate the extent
of backwardness of the economy could have been compounded
by statistical errors that remain uncorrected because
of the temporary closure of the statistical system.
It is known that GDP and revenue estimates in Afghanistan
are quite unreliable given the large role of the unaccounted,
underground economy in the country. Two factors contribute
to the magnitude of the unaccounted segments of the
economy. To start with, Afghanistan, being a landlocked
country, is also a hub for trade between some of its
larger neighbours. Such trade flows occur through
its porous borders with Pakistan (2,450 km), Tajikistan
(1,206 km), Iran (936 km), Turkmenistan (744 km),
Uzbekistan (137 km) and China (76 km). Unfortunately,
figures on Afghanistan's domestically directed and
re-export trade are not available. A June 2000–February
2001 UNDP study, based on an investigative survey
of border crossings and major trading centres, estimated
that 'indigenous exports' at $130 million constituted
just 10.6 per cent of total exports, while re-exports
totalled $1097 million (Chart 1). Similarly, imports
for domestic consumption, based on type of commodity,
amounted to $396 million (33 per cent), whereas imports
that were potentially for re-export totalled $806
million (Chart 2). It is to be expected that the huge
volume of transit or re-export trade would sustain
an economy whose activities are not fully captured
in estimates of GDP tracking the real economy. The
fact that much of this trade is not officially accounted
for is well known, so that profits accruing to Afghan
nationals from such trade (in which exports account
for more than a quarter of estimated 2002 GDP) are
also likely to be inadequately captured by national
income figures.
|
|
|
The second reason why the magnitude of the unaccounted
economy is likely to be great is the historically
important role of poppy cultivation and opium production
in the rural Afghan economy. According to an estimate
by the United Nations Office for Drug Control and
Crime Prevention, land under poppy cultivation amounted
to 82,171 hectares in 2000 and opium production in
2002 was 3,400 tons, which was similar to levels that
prevailed in the mid-to-late 1990s. With the Taliban
having imposed a ban on opium production and the Karzai
government having declared a ban on poppy cultivation
in 2002, it is inevitable that a large part of this
activity would occur in the underground economy. The
economy surrounding the cultivation of poppy, the
production of opium and its trade would generate a
significant income, which again will go substantially
unrecorded.
Ignoring the potential areas for rapid reconstruction
of war-damaged assets, the effect of prolonged drought
and the important role of unrecorded economy tends
to exaggerate the poor initial conditions, which are
then attributed solely to the long years of conflict.
This is not to say that the two-decade-long war had
no serious consequences. To start with, it did have
damaging effects on the infrastructure of the country,
created by the historically important role of foreign
aid in the country because of its strategic and transit
trade importance, making agriculture more climate
dependent, fragmenting the economy by damaging the
transportation and communications infrastructure and
generating bottlenecks in sectors like energy. Secondly,
by driving out large sections of the population and
emasculating the state it undermined the institutions
of state including the central bank, the financial
system, tax collection and customs machinery, the
statistical apparatus, the civil service, and the
law and order and judicial system. Finally, it undermined
the ability of the state to collect a share of the
surplus being generated within the economy to finance
the expenditures necessary to take on crucial governance
and development responsibilities.
With regard to the last of these effects, we must
recall that local revenue in Afghanistan comes from
its taxes on trade, much of which occurs by land across
the borders with its neighbours. A major problem being
faced by the current government in Kabul is to get
provincial governors (still referred to as warlords
by many) to part with a reasonable share of the revenue
thus garnered. Even though a meeting in May saw twelve
governors signing an agreement to do so, and one of
them delivered $20 million immediately thereafter,
it is unclear how much of the revenue will finally
accrue to the central government.
Once these features of the Afghan economy are understood
and the unwarranted hopelessness deriving from perceptions
of near-complete devastation and penury is set aside,
the direction of the aid-supported reconstruction
effort and its likely consequences can be easily deduced.
There are three pillars on which that effort should
rest: (i) restoration of the infrastructure with initial
focus on quick-impact projects that can yield substantial
benefits in a short period; (ii) restoration of the
institutions of state and the powers of those institutions
so that the state can mobilize the revenues and undertake
crucial developmental expenditures, which only it
can pursue since low per capita income levels imply
inadequate incentives for private investment in many
areas; and (iii) restoration of the 'economic space'
within which the new state can pursue a national development
agenda.
A range of specific initiatives can be identified
within this overall framework. To begin with, a greater
degree of security and an end to periodic local conflict
must be ensured. This must build on the intense and
easily observed desire of the Afghan people for peace
and the opportunity to get on with their lives and
must be secured only by an international, UN-mandated
force that is seen as a source of support and not
an instrument of occupation. Second, the damaged and
destroyed infrastructure must be immediately reconstructed,
with a large proportion of aid diverted for the purpose,
so that the economy is reintegrated and rendered functional.
Third, the ability of the state to mobilize resources
needed to finance crucial developmental responsibilities
must be restored for which an appropriate monitoring,
tax collection and revenue sharing system must be
worked out. Given the fact that Iran and Pakistan
account for a substantial share of Afghanistan's trade,
and trade revenues constitute a large share of the
total, the initial task should not be too difficult.
But over time, it would be necessary to widen the
tax base and obtain resources from internal direct
and indirect taxation, especially the former.
Fourth, it would be necessary to rebuild the financial
system with a two-fold purpose: that of mobilizing
household savings and of channelizing those savings
to priority areas, using mechanisms such as directed
credit and differential interest rates. This implies
that an overemphasis on microfinance and any neglect
of the task of creating a well-regulated formal banking
system would be misplaced. Fifth, the rural infrastructure
needed to restore dynamism to agriculture, reduce
dependence on rainfall for irrigation and encourage
growth of non-agricultural activities needs to be
created by the state.
Finally, Afghanistan needs to move out of being a
mere transit hub for trade between its neighbours
and must seek to develop activities that add value
to imported inputs to produce outputs for export and
benefit to a greater extent from its crucial role
in regional trade. The problem with the transit trade
is not that it adversely affects the balance of payments.
The field survey-based estimates quoted above show
that though there was a small deficit in terms of
the indigenously directed and originating trade, Afghanistan
did not suffer from a trade imbalance that needed
significant external financing. The real difficulty
is that unregulated growth of such trade creates disincentives
for investment aimed at increasing domestic employment
and value-added through processing and production
activities within Afghanistan.
Is this the direction in which the ostensibly UN-coordinated
reconstruction effort is heading to? Expectations
were high when, soon after the Bonn agreement that
signalled peace, a meeting of donors in Tokyo in January
2000 pledged to deliver sums, estimated at an aggregate
of $4.5 billion within a thirty-month period, to kick-start
the reconstruction effort. But a visit to Kabul, the
capital city, close to a year-and-a-half thereafter
suggests that the process of reconstruction has been
slow. The inadequacy of the reconstruction effort
is puzzling also because the limited and scattered
information on aid flows does suggest that inflows
have been significant even if not massive.
Aid flows take many forms. They occur directly to
the government, through the World Bank administered
Afghan Reconstruction Trust Fund, the Law and Order
Trust Fund (LOTF, which funds the police), the Afghanistan
Trust Fund (that pays for the army) and a number of
other channels. They occur through routes indirectly
linked to the government, inasmuch as local and international
NGOs are supported by donors to undertake projects
that are in keeping with the National Development
Framework adopted by the government in consultation
with the donor community. They also flow into areas
completely outside the governmental framework inasmuch
as US 'coalition forces', other than the International
Security Assistance Force (ISAF), and international
NGOs bring in their own funds and also in cases where
it is provided by donors abroad for activities that
are not necessarily reported in full.
The most easily accessed information is on money that
is directly contributed to the government. To coordinate
these flows, donors have constituted the ARTF in response
to a government request that the budget be made the
central instrument to identify and allocate funds
for projects. From the government's point of view,
a link with the budget would help it guide and take
credit for the reconstruction that aid permitted.
It would also ensure that aid could be used to meet
the recurrent expenditure of the government, including
a large part of its wage and salary bill. This request
was, in turn, appreciated by the donor community,
because it ensured 'national ownership' of the policies
that open or covert aid conditionality prescribed
and it ensured a degree of transparency about the
allocation and use of aid flows.
Moreover, with the ARTF being administered (for a
fee) by the World Bank, which sees in the Fund a means
of appropriating the policy leverage that the combined
aid of numerous donors provides, powerful groups within
developed-country donors were sure that their interests
would be protected. In principle, the mandate of the
ARTF is extremely wide. Besides funding the government's
recurrent expenditure including its salary bill (which
though anathema in the Bank's perspective is a source
of substantial leverage over a resource-starved state),
the ARTF can finance investment activities and programmes,
including quick-impact recovery projects, capacity-building
projects and payments made to Afghan expert-residents
abroad who are willing to temporarily or permanently
relocate to their home country. The last two of these
are also a major means of influencing the decision
making of the government.
Indications are that the Bank-led donor effort to
direct aid flows to the government and coordinate
those flows through the agencies like the ARTF and
the Afghan Assistance Coordination Authority (ACCA)
has progressed substantially. During the first full
financial year (FY) 2002–03 under the new administration
(coinciding with solar year 1381 stretching from 21
March 2002 to 20 March 2003), which came soon after
the Tokyo meet and before the aid coordination framework
could be put in place, the budget was not the principal
means of centralizing aid flows and utilization. In
April 2002, the interim administration adopted a recurrent
budget for FY 2002 involving expenditures of $483
million, including $23 million for clearance of wage
arrears. With domestic revenues estimated at $83 million,
aid was expected to finance $400 million or 83 per
cent of the budget. However, figures collated by the
ACCA indicate that total grant disbursements during
the last quarter of SY 1380 and the full SY 1381 (FY
2002) amounted to $1.84 billion, of which $295.9 went
to the government through the budget, the ARTF, the
Law and Order Trust Fund and other channels. The channels
of disbursement and the local target agency for the
remaining money are unclear, but a substantial part
($700 million according to one estimate) reportedly
went to finance humanitarian assistance in the context
of the drought.
It is in the financial year starting 21 March 2003
(SY 1382) that the process of coordinating aid flows
is being consolidated. In March 2003, the transitional
government of Afghanistan announced a comprehensive
budget for FY 2003—comprising an ordinary (recurrent)
budget of $550 million, of which $200 million is expected
to be financed with local revenues and $350 million
by external assistance, and a development budget of
about $1.7 billion. According to ACCA, by June, financing
from donors of $211.2 million for the recurrent budget
and $1.2 billion for the development budget had been
confirmed. Interestingly, only the $211.2 million
for the recurrent budget has been channelled through
the ARTF, the LOTF and the Afghanistan trust Fund,
whereas grant funding for development programmes in
the National Budget has come through other channels.
The process of using the World Bank to enforce conditionality
appears to work through a mechanism in which the Bank
controls funding for the crucial and politically sensitive
recurrent budget and thereby is able to influence
both the government's policies and its utilization
of the remaining aid provided directly to the government.
Given the funding for FY 2003 confirmed so far, expectations
are that the budgetary target for external financing
is likely to be fulfilled. The evidence collated by
the ACCA suggests that aid to the government through
various channels would by the end of FY 2003 amount
to $ 3.36 billion. Thus over a period spreading over
twenty-six months after the Tokyo meeting in January
2002, grants disbursed to the government would cover
87 per cent of the pledges made for a thirty-month
period after the meeting and 75 per cent of the total
pledges made at and after the Tokyo meeting. According
to ACCA sources, it is this high rate of disbursement
that has made the Karzai administration bid for a
$15–20 billion aid package over a five-year
period.
Though information on the flows through channels not
directed at the budget and monitored by the ACCA is
as yet difficult to come by, the actual disbursement
of aid is likely to have been substantially more than
reported above. Even though a variety of sources in
Kabul believe that the sums involved would not be
as large as that provided to the budget, it is likely
that such flows would significantly add to the total.
Thus clearly, overall disbursements have been in keeping
with the expectations generated at Tokyo.
What then accounts for the picture of a slow and clearly
inadequate pace of reconstruction? There are two obvious
reasons why aid flows have not worked to refurbish
the infrastructure, even in Kabul. To start with,
as noted earlier, a large part of the flow that occurred
prior to FY 2003 went to support the humanitarian
assistance programme to deal with the consequences
of the protracted drought and took the form of food-aid,
much of which neither involved any capital spending
nor involved expenditures in Afghanistan, since the
food was imported. Second, a large part of the grant
disbursement even in FY 2003 has gone to support the
recurrent expenditures of the government, especially
its wage and salary bill, which while spurring domestic
consumption spending, has not contributed to savings
and investment.
This use of aid to support the recurrent expenditures
of the state, including its wage bill, has a number
of implications. The inability of the government to
finance its own recurrent expenditures reflects the
fact that government in Kabul does not as yet have
the legitimacy or the power to garner a sufficient
amount of revenue that is reportedly being collected
at the provincial level. A very large proportion of
the government's 240,000 non-military personnel are
located in Kabul. This creates a situation in which
the government in Kabul is supported by the donor
community, whose leverage is therefore substantial.
Simultaneously, the expatiate presence and spending
in Kabul has generated a services-and-construction
boom there, which is bound to widen differentials
between Kabul and the rest of the country. In a country
riven with ethnic and other divisions, this distancing
of Kabul and its identification with a foreign presence
could further undermine the legitimacy of the Kabul
government, making it difficult for it to garner the
revenues it needs to do away with dependence on aid.
A consequence is that cycle of dependence of the government
on aid would only be strengthened.
The second set of reasons why aid has not created
the expected impact is related to allocation decisions.
As Chart 3 indicates, budgetary allocations for SY
1382 (FY 2003) indicate that while social sectors
like education, health and refugee rehabilitation
are allocated a total of $775 million and another
$210 million is to be spent on foreign investment
promotion, technical assistance and capacity-building
in the areas of trade and investment, public administration
and economic management and justice, only $509 million
are allocated to the crucial areas of transport and
energy, and mining and telecommunications. When seen
in terms of aid commitments to finance these expenditures
as of June 2003, this bias appears even greater (Chart
4). Thus part of the reason for slow reconstruction
of infrastructure is that a small part of even the
development budget is being allocated for the purpose.
|
|
|
This overemphasis on technical assistance and capacity
building is justified in the name of reconstituting
the damaged Afghan state. Much of the money under
these heads goes to institutions like the Adam Smith
Institute and expatriate professionals who are paid
huge consultancy fees in foreign currency, not all
of which is even spent in Afghanistan. A constant
refrain heard among the expatriate population in Kabul
is that Afghans lack the capacity to manage their
own affairs. Despite the fact that these institutions
and most NGOs manage their programmes, especially
those outside Kabul, with the aid of local partners,
and though many skilled personnel who left as refugees
to Pakistan, Iran and elsewhere have returned, this
perspective overwhelmingly influences the management
of aid-financed programmes. It almost appears that
the "lack of capacity" discourse supports
a nexus of aid-financed professionals, who find in
such arguments the justification of their own dollar-funded
presence in the country, and of aid donors, especially
agencies such as the World Bank, who can use those
arguments to prevent the entry of those more nationalistic
in orientation into the decision-making and implementation
process. This is not a fact that goes unnoticed among
the Afghan population. Interviews with Afghan professionals
and members of the faculty at the University of Kabul
inevitably generate comments to the effect that Afghan
talent, more attuned to the socio-cultural and economic
context of the country, is being ignored, while expatriate
and non-resident Afghan "experts" are imported
even when not required.
The still-evolving policy framework in Afghanistan
provides reasons why nationalistic perceptions may
be considered dispensable. It is to be expected that
with government expenditure substantially driven by
aid disbursements, explicit and implicit aid conditionality
is bound to influence the policy framework. The effort,
therefore, is to ensure that those manning the government
"own" the policies that such conditionality
implies. Unfortunately that policy framework is not
of a kind that could support the creation of a "domestic
economic space" within which the Afghan state
can fashion a nationally beneficial and egalitarian
development strategy. Though the government's donor-driven
strategy is yet in the making, it is clear that the
inevitable import dependence of a war-devastated economy
is being intensified, by encouraging an open trade
policy that would discourage domestic industrial investment.
Crucial social sector areas like health provision
are being handed over to private entities and NGOs
to run at a price, which though currently subsidized
by aid, could easily be charged to the user at a later
date.
The state has adopted as law the principle that the
central bank cannot lend to the government. Thus deficit-financed
expenditure to revive the economy is ruled out, resulting
in a near-complete dependence on aid for budgetary
finance. The battered publicly-owned financial sector,
rather than being supported and strengthened, in order
to be leveraged for domestic industrial financing,
is soon to be subjected to competition from private,
especially foreign, players. Since the need for a
banking system that can mobilize local savings and
channelize it to priority investments crucial to domestic
private sector development is great, this shift can
be disastrous. Foreign banks would only wean away
the most lucrative (mainly expatriate) businesses
from the local, publicly owned banking sector, while
refusing to take any responsibility for development.
Finally, though the new Afghani is formally the national
currency, aid flows and the expatriate presence is
dollarising the economy with the dollar being traded
on the streets and many service establishments quoting
dollar prices and expecting payment in dollars.
These developments proceed unchallenged partly because
a vocal, urban domestic elite is being incorporated
into the aid economy. Not only are salaries paid on
time with the help of aid, but the demand for services
from the expatriate population is on the rise. Rents
quoted in dollars are rising fast because of the expatriate
rush into Kabul and some other cities. These and other
opportunities are resulting in the emergence of a
new class of richer Afghans, living off the aid economy,
which is happy with the freedom that an open, dollarised
economy provides.
All this is fine at the moment since aid flows are
leading to foreign exchange reserve accumulation with
the central bank, which can use those reserves when
required to prop up the new Afghani and prevent local
prices of imported commodities from rising. But in
the medium term, aid, import-dependence and dollarisation
can all prove a burden. If the pace of aid inflow
slows, not only will the just-reviving economy contract
but the Afghani would depreciate pushing up the prices
of essentials in that segment of the economy still
earning and living off the local currency. Stagflation,
in an already depressed economy, would be the result.
On the other hand, if aid inflows continue at present
levels or rise in volume, inequalities between Kabul
and the rest of the country, across differentially
endowed regions and between income classes are bound
to increase. That can have dangerous implications
in a country that is still scarred by a complex chain
of civil strife influenced by ethnic and religious
divides.
The current model of development in Afghanistan is
clearly unsustainable for any discerning observer.
But for those present in the country with short-term
military and economic interests in mind, who are protected
by the façade of altruism that a small dose
of aid to a poor and devastated nation helps provide,
this appears to be of no concern.
The author wishes to gratefully
acknowledge support from the ActionAid Regional Bureau,
Bangkok and the Action Aid Afghanistan Office for
the research on which this article is based. He also
benefited immensely from discussions with Bijay Kumar,
Essa Shamal, Phillippa Sackett, S. Parasuraman and
P.V. Unnikrishnan.
July 23, 2003.
|