The
possibility of volatile movements of capital has become
one of the most significant issues in developing countries
today. Of course it is a problem in itself, since
rapid movements in and out of the country create instability
in exchange rates and consequent problems within the
economy. But even more than that, the fear of capital
flight has posed substantial constraints upon domestic
economic policies across the developing world.
Governments now worry before engaging in the most
basic of fiscal and monetary policies that would be
targeted towards improving the welfare of their citizens,
simply because they are concerned that international
finance may express its displeasure at anything that
curtails its profits, by causing a currency crisis.
For this reason, it is extremely important for governments
to continue to maintain some measures that will allow
them to regulate capital flows. It is important to
note that controls on the inflows of capital are as
important as controls on outflows, since sudden large
inflows can be as destabilising for an economy as
outflows. Indeed, the history of currency crises in
the past decade proves that it is those countries
that were suddenly “favoured” by international
finance and received large inflows, that subsequently
also faced financial crises because of sudden outflows.
Partly, this is because large inflows which are coming
in for speculative purposes put upward pressure on
the exchange rate, causing the currency to appreciate.
This then creates tendencies whereby the current account
deficit increases, and over time, this leads to a
“loss of confidence” on the part of international
investors. The countries that have avoided such financial
crises even when all around them other countries in
the same region have fallen victim to them, are precisely
those countries that have continued to maintain some
degree of controls on the movements of capital in
and out of the country.
Even in India, the large inflows of capital over the
past two years, while not yet precipitating a crisis,
have been unnecessary and expensive for the government.
These inflows did not involve increases in investment
but were largely been directed towards speculative
activity in the stock market, and also led to large
increases in the foreign exchange reserves held by
the RBI. Since these reserves are held in safe areas
which provide very low return, especially in relation
to the rate of interest on external commercial borrowing,
holding them has actually been quite costly for the
Indian economy.
Some people argue that holding these huge reserves
is necessary to prevent possible currency crises,
but the experience of other countries shows that even
very large reserves are rarely proof against determined
speculators. In any case, a much simpler method of
avoiding such crises is to provide for regulation
that will smoothen both inflows and outflows.
This issue is of special concern in India today because
the current government has already declared its intention
to undertake a number of policies which fly in the
face of the market-determined strategy. These include
an emphasis on public investment especially in the
rural areas, a rural employment guarantee scheme,
an increase in the tax-GDP ratio. None of these are
likely to find much favour with speculative capital,
which is why it is quite possible that some measures
which result from these aims will lead to pressure
for capital flight.
For this reason, it is important to have an array
of instruments available to control the movement of
capital, prevent crises and ensure that capital inflows
are directed towards the best uses within the economy.
There is already a large set of controls which have
been used quite recently (and continue to be used
in some countries) which provide good examples. It
is not only the more well-known example of China,
or India’s own past, which provides such instances.
Capital controls of varying sorts have been used to
effect in recent times by countries ranging from Chile
and Colombia to Taiwan province of China and Singapore.
Some possibilities are briefly mentioned here.
To begin with, of course, there are the more obvious
direct controls which regulate the actual volume of
inflow or outflow in quantitative terms. These can
relate to Foreign Direct Investment and to external
borrowing by residents as well as to portfolio capital
flows. In addition, these can be directed within the
economy towards particular sectors or recipients through
positive or negative lists.
But there are also more indirect or market-based methods
which have been increasingly used to regulate capital
movements. Several countries have specified a minimum
residence requirement (of 1-3 years) on portfolio
capital inflows and also on FDI. Chile and Colombia
had provided for a non-interest bearing reserve requirement
(of between 33 per cent and as much as 48 per cent
of the total inflow) to be held for one year with
the central bank, to ensure that the inflows were
not of a speculative nature.
For portfolio capital, other specific measures are
possible. In some countries foreigners are prevented
from purchasing domestic debt instruments and corporate
equity. The extent of FPI penetration in the domestic
stock market can be regulated, with a limit on the
proportion of stocks held by such foreign investors.
There can be exit levies which are inversely proportional
to the length of the stay, such that capital which
leaves the country sooner has to pay a higher tax.
In any case, differential rates of taxation provide
an important means of regulating capital flows.
In the case of external commercial borrowing, some
countries have imposed a tax on foreign loans. Others
have provided fiscal incentives for domestic borrowing
and investment. Domestic banking regulations can also
play an important role in ensuring that private external
debt does not reach undesirable proportions and to
direct resources towards particular sectors.
The financial press tends to portray such controls
as rigid and acting as disincentives to investment.
But the reality is very different – experience
shows that these controls can be and have been used
flexibly and changed in response to changing circumstances.
Furthermore, they have typically not acted as disincentive
to continued capital inflows of the desired variety;
instead, they have ensured that such inflows actually
contribute to increasing investment in socially effective
ways. It is worth noting that China, which still retains
the largest number and most comprehensive of controls
over all forms of capital flow among all countries,
has also been the largest recipient of capital inflows
in the developing world.
So the new government must recognise that capital
controls have to form a basic part of the overall
economic strategy. Such controls must be over both
inflows and outflows, and be flexible and responsive
to change. But without them, it is difficult to see
how other aspects of the planned economic programme
can be implemented effectively.
July 5, 2004.
|