For
several centuries - between the 15th and the early
19th centuries - mercantilist theories dominated the
attitude to trade in Europe. This was the belief that
an economy that had positive net exports (through
exports being greater than imports) would be wealthier
because it would lead to an inflow of bullion, or
assets, and thereby increase its economic strength.
This approach led to economic policies designed to
increase exports and suppress imports, trade wars,
and even the colonial wars that were crucial to ensuring
markets for the various European powers.
There were of course many flaws of mercantilist theories,
most notably the confusion of bullion with real economic
wealth, the lack of recognition of the various benefits
of greater trade independent of the trade balance,
and the failure to perceive that the purpose of increasing
exports is to be able to import more, and thus raise
the level and variety of consumption in the society.
For a relatively long time, mercantilist arguments
have been discredited. But recently, a new form of
neo-mercantilism has emerged and has propelled the
economic models of the two economies that are increasingly
seen as the most successful and potentially powerful
in the world: China and Germany.
Mercantilism - the obsession with net exports - is
often seen as identical with export-led growth, but
in fact the two are not the same. It is possible to
have exports as the basic engine or driver of growth
without necessarily running a trade surplus. All that
is required is that export demand becomes a catalyst
for growth in the rest of the system and generates
additional demand.
Indeed, some of the classic examples of recent export-led
growth, such as the East Asian “dragons” or the Southeast
Asian economies, generally ran trade deficits during
their period of high export-led growth. Even China's
trade surpluses are of relatively recent vintage,
since the country had trade deficits during the period
of rapid export growth from the early 1980s to the
late 1990s, and only started having large trade surplus
in the early part of the 2000s.
However, for the last decade in particular, both China
and Germany have been increasingly reliant on a strategy
of growth that requires pushing out more and more
net exports. This in turn has required suppressing
domestic wages and consumption. In China the consumption
to GDP ratio fell from 46 per cent of GDP in 2000
to less than 36 per cent in 2007, while in Germany
it fell from 60 per cent to 56.5 per cent in the same
period.
Why would such a strategy be attractive at all? After
all, no one really still believes that an inflow of
bullion (or a net accumulation of financial assets,
which amounts to the same thing) is of great intrinsic
value for an economy. It could be argued that the
current strategy is based on a different notion of
the gain; one which recognizes the absence of full
employment and seeks to use trade as a means of maximizing
employment. Thus net exports are valued because they
involve more productive jobs at home and less leakage
of jobs through imports. To that extent, this is also
a form of beggar-thy-neighbour economic strategy,
since it involves creating or preserving jobs in your
own country at the expense of jobs in your trade partners.
This argument too is essentially fallacious, because
it does not recognise that while trade can affect
the pattern of employment, the aggregate level of
employment is determined by macroeconomic policies.
The possibility of employment in non-tradable activities
making up for employment losses through trade (which
would have to be the result of active government intervention
as well) is not considered.
Despite this, the urge to generate trade surpluses
has become an important plank of the overall economic
strategy in both countries. It is possibly even more
marked in Germany than in China, which has seen some
recent moves to develop the home market.
Even more than export-led growth per se, such a strategy
involves a fallacy of composition, in that all countries
cannot pursue it. Indeed, the dependence of the surplus
economies on the existence of other countries that
are simultaneously running deficits is only too obvious.
In the recent past, that has come from a combination
of one large global player (the US economy, which
has served as the engine of growth for much of the
rest of the world) and a number of smaller economies
running smaller deficits financed by capital flows.
This gives rise to a classic dilemma of mercantilist
strategy, which is evident in an exaggerated form
today for the neo-mercantilist economies: they are
forced to finance the deficits of those countries
that would buy their products, through capital flows
that sustain the demand for their own exports. Thus
it is no accident that China and Germany are both
large investors in the US and purchasers of US Treasury
Bills, or that German banks are heavily implicated
in lending to the now-fragile deficit economies in
the European Union.
Despite these contradictions and dilemmas, such a
strategy can certainly be successful for a while,
and this can be true even over the economic cycle.
This is evident from Chart 1, which shows how both
China and Germany experienced very sharp declines
in export growth in the wake of the recent global
crisis, but have since rebounded sharply.
(It should be noted that all charts refer to merchandise
trade only.)
Interestingly, Chart 1 also shows
how the United States economy had been showing reasonably
high export growth before the crisis and how its export
growth has also revived (largely related to dollar
devaluation) in the most recent period.
Chart 2 indicates how the trade surpluses of these
two mercantilist economies are related to the deficits
run by the US. The US deficit is obviously much larger
than the combined surpluses of these two countries,
but as it has shrunk slightly in the wake of the crisis,
so have their surpluses.
Nevertheless, both countries have
maintained the tendency to generating trade surpluses,
alough there has been some shift within China. In
Germany, the ability to impose wage restraint throughout
the period of economic boom and rising labour productivity
were remarkable in their scope, and critical to the
enhanced competitiveness of the economy. During the
crisis, employment levels fell relatively little,
not only because of the existence of automatic stabilisers
that provided a countercyclical cushion for the economy,
but also the willingness of German workers in export
industries to accept effective wage cuts rather than
lose employment.
In any case in Germany, a significant part of the
export surplus is generated from trade with other
partners in the Euopean Union (EU). Intra-EU trade
accounts for around two-thirds of total EU trade,
and an equivalent part of German trade as well. Chart
3 shows how movements in Germany's trade surpluse
have been closely mirrored by movements in the aggregate
deficit of all other EU countries.
It is this misalignment within Europe
that is at the heart of the economic problems faced
by many deficit countries in the region today. There
is a basic difference between price levels in Gemany
and most other EU members, resulting from the fact
that Germany has been able to keep wages nearly stagnant
even with rapid labour productivity increases, while
other countries are not able to let the gap between
wages and productivity widen to that extent. This
means that prices of many goods and servies are significantly
lower (sometimes by as much as one-third) in Germany
compared to most other European economies.
Remarkably, therefore, there are real exchange rate
mismatches within a common currency area. Obviously
this reflects another significant failure, that of
the European Single Market to ensure price arbitrage
of traded goods, or wage equalisation through the
movement of labour.
What is more significant for present purposes is that
such mismatches cannot continue indefinitely. Already
the deficit countries in Europe - not only those whose
goverments' bond markets are in difficulties but others
as well - are being forced to cut down on imports
through very severe austerity measures that are reducing
both output and employment. Ironically, such moves
are being strongly pushed by the German government
inside the EU, even though this is likely to rebound
adversely on the German capacity to generate export
surpluses.
In the US, the external adjustment will also clearly
occur, whether through exchange rate movements or
increased protectionism, or in any other manner. Chart
4 suggests that this process is already underway:
although import levels of both the US and non-Germany
EU have recovered slightly from the trough of early
2009, they are still far below the earlier peaks and
also appear to be levelling off despite the recent
output recovery.
So, while the neo-mercantilist strategy
can be apparently successful for a while, it is likely
to come up against both internal and external constraints.
Internally, the potential for suppression of wage
incomes and domestic consumption will meet with political
resistance. Externally, deficit countries will either
choose or be forced to reduce their deficits through
various means. In either case, the pressures to find
more sustainable sources of economic growth, particularly
through domestic demand and wage-led alternatives,
are likely to increase.
September 7, 2010.
|