Discussions
of the current world economic crisis tend to focus
exclusively on the bursting of the housing bubble
in the United States. This no doubt is the immediate
cause of the crisis, but underlying its operation
is the fact that the stimulus for booms in contemporary
capitalism has increasingly come from such bubbles.
The U.S. whose size and strength make it, in the current
regime of trade liberalization, the main determinant
of the pace of expansion of the world economy as a
whole, has increasingly come to rely on such bubbles
to initiate and sustain booms. The dot-com bubble
whose bursting had caused the previous crisis was
followed by the housing bubble which started a new
boom. This has now come to an end, precipitating a
major financial crisis and initiating what looks like
a major depression reminiscent of the 1930s.
John Maynard Keynes, writing in the midst of that
Depression, had located the fundamental defect of
the free market system in its incapacity to distinguish
between “enterprise” and “speculation” and hence in
its tendency to get dominated by speculators, interested
not in the long-term yield on assets but only in the
short-term appreciation in asset values. Their whims
and caprices, causing sharp swings in asset prices,
determined the magnitude of productive investment
and hence the level of aggregate demand, employment
and output in the economy. The real lives of millions
of people were determined by the whims of a bunch
of speculators under the free market system.
Keynes wanted this link to be severed through what
he called a comprehensive “socialization” of investment,
whereby the State acting on behalf of society always
ensured a level of investment in the economy, and
hence a level of aggregate demand, that was adequate
for full employment. This prescription entailed not
only a jettisoning of the free market system in favour
of State intervention, but restraints on the free
global mobility of finance, since meaningful State
intervention could not be possible if the nation-State
faced internationally-mobile capital. “Finance above
all must be national”, he had said, if the State had
to have the autonomy to intervene meaningfully in
the economy.
The process of globalization, involving above all
the globalization of finance, which began during the
period of Keynesian demand management itself, has
undermined Keynesian demand management in the capitalist
countries, and removed a whole host of regulatory
measures that characterized the Keynesian regime.
Boosts to aggregate demand have of late come increasingly
from the stimulation of private expenditure, associated
with the creation of bubbles in asset prices, rather
than from an adjustment of public expenditure within
the context of reasonably stable asset prices. The
reliance on bubbles in short has acted as a substitute
for the earlier regime of Keynesian demand management;
it is management through the creation and sustenance
of bubbles rather than through the pace of public
spending. Not surprisingly, the frequency of financial
crises, associated with the bursting of these bubbles,
has increased greatly after 1973, and we are now even
headed for a major crash.
Governments in advanced countries have still not recognized
this onset of a crash. They have proceeded on the
assumption that the injection of liquidity into the
system is all that is needed. It was thought initially
that this injection could be achieved through the
government purchase of “toxic” securities, but widespread
opposition to that scheme has now made most governments
accept the idea of injection of liquidity in lieu
of equity, i.e. through the part-nationalization of
financial institutions.
But injection of liquidity, even in this manner, is
not enough. Credit will not start flowing simply because
banks can access more liquidity. There has to be adequate
demand for credit for viable projects by solvent and
worthwhile borrowers. And this is not happening. First,
the injection of liquidity does not improve the solvency
of firms saddled with “toxic” securities, so that
the risk associated with lending to them remains prohibitively
high. And secondly, quite apart from this, the anticipation
of a Depression makes borrowers chary of borrowing
and lenders chary of lending.
This anticipation in turn derives from several factors:
first, the bursting of one bubble is not necessarily
succeeded by the immediate formation of another, so
that some recession of a more or less prolonged duration
is in any case inevitable. Secondly, the very scale
of the current financial crisis is such as to entail
an anticipation of a prolonged recession. And thirdly,
since the recession has already started, the prospects
of crisis-prevention now through the usual monetary
instruments (including liquidity injection) appear
distinctly dim. The scenario, in which tendencies
towards increased liquidity preference on the part
of private individuals and institutions and a downward
slide in the real economy mutually reinforce one another,
has already started unfolding itself and will continue
for a prolonged period, unless governments now act
to inject demand into the economy directly, apart
from injecting liquidity. Until this happens on a
large enough scale the Depression will persist.
The third world countries will not escape the effects
of this Depression. True, many of them whose financial
systems are still not sufficiently “opened up” and
hence have not been “contaminated” by any links to
“toxic” securities, will escape the direct impact
of the world financial crisis (though even they cannot
escape some “sympathetic” movements in their financial
markets as well). But they certainly will have to
face the impact of the Depression of the real economy.
Their export earnings, both merchandise and invisibles,
will be hit, causing unemployment and output contraction
on the one hand, and foreign exchange crisis, exchange
rate depreciation and accentuated inflation on the
other. (The latter will be aggravated by the outflow
of speculative capital that had come in earlier to
the “newly emerging markets” under the auspices of
Foreign Institutional Investors).
Two areas are of special concern here. One is the
inevitable decline in the terms of trade for primary
commodities that will occur in a Depression, which
will push cash-crop growing peasants into even greater
distress and destitution and into even larger mass
suicides. (These have been already occurring for some
time on a disturbing scale in countries like India).
The second is the loss of food security over much
of the third world that will inevitably occur. There
are at least three mutually-reinforcing reasons for
this: first, the loss of foreign exchange earnings
owing to the decline in exports and in the terms of
trade will cause a decline in foodgrain availability
in food-importing countries owing to a decline in
their import capacity. Secondly, even if food availability
is somehow maintained, the decline in the incomes
of exporting peasants and small producers and of those
affected by the rise in unemployment will mean that
large masses of people will simply lack the purchasing
power to buy necessary food. And thirdly, if the terms
of trade of non-food primary commodities decline relative
to food, as has been happening for some time now,
then both the above problems will be greatly aggravated.
There is a tragic irony here. The booms fed by asset
price bubbles not only did not benefit the large mass
of peasants, petty producers, agricultural labourers,
craftsmen, and industrial workers in the third world,
but were actually accompanied by an absolute deterioration
in their living standards. This happened not despite
the boom but because of it, in a number of ways. First,
with the interlinking of global financial markets,
asset price booms in the US tended to produce stock
market booms, and more generally financial sector
booms, even in third world countries, where banks
and other financial institutions withdrew from productive
sector lending to speculative lending, from rural
to urban lending and from agriculture and small-scale
sector lending to consumer credit to the affluent
and loans against securities. This damaged the productive
base of the peasant and small-scale sector. Secondly,
the changed role of the State in the new dispensation
where it was more concerned with supporting the financial
sector boom and in maintaining “the confidence of
the investors” than with sustaining peasant and petty
production, entailed a withdrawal of State support
from the latter sector: input subsidies, the price
support system, essential public investment, and State
spending on rural infrastructure and on social sectors,
were all drastically curtailed; and without them the
entire small producer economy became submerged in
crisis.
A simple statistic illustrates the point. In 1980,
the per capita cereal output in the world was 355
kilogrammes. By 2000 it had fallen to 341 kilogrammes.
This absolute decline in per capita cereal output
meant also an absolute decline in per capita cereal
consumption for the world as a whole. But since per
capita cereal consumption, taking both direct and
indirect consumption into account, increased for the
advanced countries, the overall decline for the world
as a whole was caused by a massive decline in the
third world countries, where even countries like China
and India which experienced remarkably high GDP growth
rates, did not escape this trend.
The fact that this decline in per capita cereal output
in the world economy was not accompanied by any rise
in relative cereal prices (in fact between these two
years the terms of trade of cereals visavis manufacturing
in the world economy declined by 40 percent), even
when the per capita income in the world economy was
increasing quite noticeably, suggests that the squeeze
on the purchasing power of the masses in the third
world was even greater. The other side of the speculative
boom occurring in a deregulated and financially-interlinked
capitalist world therefore was a drastic squeeze on
the living standards of the masses, especially n the
third world (which incidentally is one reason why
the “locomotive” analogy often given for the US economy’s
role in the world economy is so inapposite: this locomotive
while pulling some coaches, pushes back some others).
But even though the masses suffered from the effects
of the speculative boom, they would also suffer additionally
from the effects of its collapse. We do not have a
symmetry here between the effects of booms and of
depressions, and herein lies the tragic irony of the
situation.
It is clear from the above that the need of the hour
is not just the injection of liquidity into the world
economy but also in addition the injection of demand.
This can occur only through direct fiscal action by
governments across the world. For activating governments
for this, control over cross-border capital flows
is essential, for otherwise governments will continue
to remain prisoners to the caprices of globally-mobile
speculative finance capital. The sectors where government
spending will go up will of course vary from country
to country, but the general objective of such spending
must be the reversal of the squeeze on the living
standards of the ordinary people everywhere in the
world that has been a feature of the world economy
in the last several years. In the United States government
spending may have to take the form of increasing the
social wage and enlarging welfare state activities
generally, increasing infrastructure expenditure and
to making more funds available to states through federal
transfers. But in India, China and other third world
countries, in addition to welfare state measures,
larger government expenditure has to be oriented towards
a substantial increase in agricultural, especially
foodgrains, output.
Taking the world economy as a whole, the new growth
stimulus will have to come not from some new speculative
bubble but from enlarged government expenditure that
directly improves the livelihoods of the people, both
in the advanced and in the developing economies, and
that is geared towards improving the foodgrain output
of the world through a revamping of peasant agriculture
(and not through corporate farming, since that would
reduce purchasing power in the hands of the peasantry
and perpetuate its distress). In short, the new paradigm
must entail a foodgrain-led growth strategy (on the
basis of peasant agriculture), sustained through larger
government spending towards this end, which simultaneously
rids the world of both depression and financial and
food crises. The trade and financial arrangements
of the world economy have to be oriented towards achieving
this rather than being made to conform to some a priori
free market principles that have the effect of pushing
the world economy into financial crises and slumps,
and the peasantry and small producers of the world
into destitution both during the booms and also, additionally,
during the slumps.
October
13, 2008.
|