In
a recent article entitled Reforming the World Bank:
Creative Destruction (Foreign Affairs, January/February
2006), Jessica Einhorn, dean of the Paul H. Nitze
School of Advanced International Studies (SAIS, Johns
Hopkins University), called for the disbandment of
the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
(IBRD). Addressing her remarks to the World Bank's
new president, Paul Wolfowitz [1]
and its major funders, she called for an end
to the bank's lending to middle-income countries,
and for a focus instead on the poorer countries which
have little or no access to private capital markets
as credit sources for development financing.
Einhorn, who retired in 1998 as managing director
of the World Bank (shorthand for the "World Bank
Group" which includes the International Bank
for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD), lending
to the governments of middle- and lower-middle income
countries at commercial rates, the International Development
Association (IDA), which provides easier credit terms
and grants (with conditionalities) to the poorest
countries, and the International Finance Corporation
(IFC), which promotes private sector involvement in
development and its financing) may seem to have found
common cause with NGO critics campaigning against
the Bretton Woods institutions (BWIs).
Their motivations in fact are quite the opposite.
Focus on the Global South for instance regards the
BWIs as instruments of metropolitan capital by and
large, as enthusiastic purveyors of the neo-liberal
agenda, and call for their dismantling and replacement
by more accountable and people-responsive institutions
for development financing.
Einhorn, who echoes the call to wind down the IBRD,
seeks however to extend the neo-liberal agenda to
the World Bank itself (in effect, outsourcing the
IBRD's lending activities to private capital markets),
with her call for "targeted" development
financing:
In the World Bank's first years of existence,
the IBRD dominated the institution. Now, however,
lending to middle-income countries has diminished
in both size and emphasis: the IBRD's gross disbursements
have declined from nominal levels of $13-14 billion
a decade ago to about $10 billion in fiscal years
2004 and 2005. Private capital flows to emerging markets
[by comparison have increased to] over $300 billion
a year. The IBRD seems to be a dying institution…
some countries that originally depended on IBRD lending
no longer need the IBRD because they can get funding
from private sources… The financial markets of today
bear no similarity to those of 1944… The whole concept
of a lending institution with a big balance sheet
tied up in long-term loans has been overtaken by securitization,
in which loans are just the starting point for packaging
together securities that can be sold and traded in
the marketplace. Looking ahead ten years, the growth
of the market for credit derivatives will most likely
mean that credit to middle-income countries will be
just another derivative financial instrument - to
be bought, sold, and managed in private portfolios.
On the eve of the East Asian currency crisis, the
IMF quarterly Finance & Development reported in
June 1997 that official development finance (grants
and loans) had declined from US$56.3 billion in 1990
to US$40.8 billion in 1996 ("Developing countries
get more private investment, less aid"). Concessional
aid and grants, increasingly targeted at refugee and
emergency relief, held fairly steady at about US$30
billion annually, but the non-concessional loan component
of official development finance fell from US$27.1
billion (1990) to US$9.5 billion in 1996. Over the
same period however, private capital flows (commercial
bank loans, bonds, foreign direct investment, and
portfolio equity investments) increased dramatically
from US$44.4 billion to US$243.8 billion.
The World Bank's counterpart publication Global Development
Finance reported in 2001 that "in real terms,
concessional [aid] flows worldwide increased by nearly
50% between 1970 and 1980, and by 32% in the ensuing
decade. They then plunged 25% in the 1990s… concessional
flows have risen modestly since 1997… reflects some
temporary factors, notably the rise in Japanese aid
in response to the financial crisis in East Asia…
However concessional aid in 2000 was still much less
than in the early 1990s… total official development
finance – concessional and non-concessional resources
– to developing countries was US$38.6 billion in 2000,
another significant decline after the steep drop in
1999 [US$45.3 billion, down from US$54.6 billion in
1998]. The decline was due to non-concessional flows
that fell back again in 2000, reflecting the ability
of some countries to prepay on rescue packages as
they emerged from the global financial crisis [and
duly] returned to market-based financing from commercial
sources".
The privatization of the IBRD should come as no surprise.
Global production overcapacity, massive increases
in speculative financial flows, historically low interest
rates, property and asset bubbles, and resurgent militarist
Keynesianism are expressions of a systemic glut of
capital that has been building up over several decades,
ceaselessly seeking out profitable outlets for deployment
and redeployment.
Likewise, the neo-liberal agenda of privatization,
market creation and market deepening, and retrenchment
of the welfarist-cum-developmentalist state, is driven
by over-accumulated capital seeking to extend its
circuits into hitherto non-commercial public sector
domains for continued accumulation.
As an agent of global social reproduction, the World
Bank itself is also subject to forces pushing for
privatization (in this case, divestment of its development
financing role to private capital markets), much in
the way that welfarist states are urged to selectively
offload their more profitable (or commercially viable)
social services to the private sector.
Not surprisingly (as an institutional compromise and
accommodation), the World Bank, without requiring
much of a push, seems to have re-positioned itself
to be an even more influential agent which can promote
the privatization and retrenchment of the welfarist/
developmentalist state.
We see, for instance, expanded roles for the IFC and
the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA)
within the World Bank Group (IFC and MIGA commitments
rose from 3.3% of World Bank loans in 1980 to 25%
in 2000); World Bank bonds, first issued in 1989 to
raise funds in private capital markets to make up
for funding shortfalls from donor countries (up to
80% of the bank's funds now come from the sale of
bonds); World Bank Institute, a reorganized ideological
hub to propagate more vigorously the neo-liberal agenda
through a global network of affiliated and influential
think-tanks, in the process, disingenuously exaggerating
the role of the "free" market in fostering
"development", and denigrating the state-led
experiences of much of East & Southeast Asia.
(Notwithstanding these efforts, the BWIs' reputations
and influence have been battered of late, in much
of Latin America, most notably Argentina, in East
Asia in the wake of the 1997 currency crises, in the
ex-Soviet states, and by high profile defections such
as the Nobel economics laureate Joseph Stiglitz).
Since the time of AW Clausen (World Bank president,
1981-1986, former president Bank of America, not coincidentally
a time when metropolitan banks were flush with liquidity
from Eurodollars and petrodollars), there had been
persistent calls from certain US quarters for the
BWIs to divest more of their development financing
activities to private capital markets. The same interests
presumably are among the perennial chorus clamoring
to reduce US contributions to multilateral lending
agencies.
The Meltzer Commission, in its report to the US Congress
in 2000, recommended in effect a triage of borrower
countries: debt cancellation, outright grants and
performance-based concessional loans for the most
destitute of highly-indebted countries, as opposed
to the more "credit-worthy" borrowers with
access to capital markets, who should be weaned from
multilateral lending agencies and henceforth be serviced
by private lending institutions (i.e. the financial
analogue of "targeted" programs in health
services). Indeed, this is the persuasive face and
generic template for the privatization of social services.
There's perhaps a moral to this tale: Be careful what
you ask for, because you may get it. Well, not quite.
The IBRD of course has its own entrenched interests
and institutional staying power. Einhorn hints at
the outlines of a possible compromise for a downsized
IBRD in her concluding remarks:
Any advocate of reform must be frank about the
bureaucratic interests that currently want the IBRD
to survive as long as possible. The IBRD has become
a crucial source of financial support and clout for
the development community. IBRD income helps sustain
the World Bank's administrative budget of $2 billion
and finances large off-budget transfers of money to
IDA countries ($600 million in the last fiscal year
alone)…The G-20 [governments] should convene a group
of eminent persons from outside of government, led
by a distinguished former finance minister or head
of government from a middle-income country, for the
purpose of considering the ideal institution to meet
the needs of middle-income countries. In providing
the option of an orderly and consensual way to shut
down the IBRD, the group…could appoint a team of able
and prudent financial engineers, headed by a retired
central-bank governor, to elaborate a set of modern
financial designs for meeting whatever needs the group
envisions, such as grants for technology research
or a credit backstop facility using derivative instruments
to insure loans made to developing countries. The
new institution would be free to join its operations
with the IFC and the Multilateral Investment Guarantee
Agency to promote private sector involvement in novel
ways. No sovereign guarantee would be required, and
lending, investment, or guarantees could occur at
the local, regional, or even global level—to support
initiatives for the global commons, for example.
Learning from their experiences during the Third World
debt crises of the 1980s, private financial capital
will find it useful to retain an institutional intermediary
which underwrites or absorbs the financial risks of
development lending. Rather than assume the risks
directly as they did with their reckless lending in
the Third World in the 1970s and 1980s (and then relying
on the BWIs' muscle for debt collection when the loans
went sour), finance capital much prefers to mitigate
these risks, via World Bank bonds and other financial
instruments, or offload them onto a rump IBRD working
in conjunction with the IFC and MIGA to facilitate
"public-private partnerships" in development
financing.
The substance of such "public-private partnerships"
is evident from this Economist (February 13, 1999)
report:
"traditionally, the World Bank's main products
have been loans. But in recent years it has offered
partial guarantees for investment projects as well,
taking on some of the risks that investors eschew…World
Bank guarantees [for sovereign or corporate bonds]
have many advantages over loans. They help countries
to regain access to private capital markets, can be
tailored to cover the particular risks that worry
investors most, and can help countries extend the
maturities of their borrowing. Those inside the Bank
who deal with guarantees reckon that perhaps a dozen
such deals could be done a year. Yet some of their
colleagues are skeptical. They point out that private
money with a World Bank guarantee costs a country
more than a straight World Bank loan. They worry that
such guarantees are an inefficient use of Bank money:
under the Bank's conservative rules, guarantees must
be accounted for (on a net present value basis) exactly
as if they were loans. They fret about "stripping":
that investors would repackage the bonds, selling
the World Bank's guarantees separately in a way that
might raise the Bank's own borrowing costs. For a
guarantee to be acceptable to investors, it has to
be irrevocable; once a bond is guaranteed, the World
Bank is committed"
As with the shriveling welfarist states, the rump
IBRD would also retain those tasks which remain unattractive
to private capital - unprofitable or uncommodifiable
services, global public goods and global commons,
and externalities which accrue for example from the
development of vaccines and drugs for neglected diseases,
or research into environmentally-friendly technologies
or measures to cope with threatening emergent pandemics.
The poorer credit risks for sovereign lending of course
would remain the province of the IDA, which might
then face more straitened circumstances arising from
reduced off-budget transfers (cross subsidies) from
IBRD incomes, and become increasingly dependent on
the tender mercies of "philanthropic Keynesianism"
a la Gates.
The IBRD is deservedly castigated by social activists
for its many failings. Einhorn's proposals for privatizing
development financing however do not address the needs
of the people of the South. They pander to the priorities
and dictates of global finance capital.
February 22, 2006.
* School of Social Sciences, Universiti
Sains Malaysia, 11800 Penang, Malaysia ckchan50@yahoo.com
[1] her predecessor as SAIS dean but
better known as the former deputy to US War Secretary
Donald Rumsfeld.
|